Discover millions of ebooks, audiobooks, and so much more with a free trial

Only $11.99/month after trial. Cancel anytime.

Boilerplate: The Fine Print, Vanishing Rights, and the Rule of Law
Boilerplate: The Fine Print, Vanishing Rights, and the Rule of Law
Boilerplate: The Fine Print, Vanishing Rights, and the Rule of Law
Ebook460 pages6 hours

Boilerplate: The Fine Print, Vanishing Rights, and the Rule of Law

Rating: 4 out of 5 stars

4/5

()

Read preview

About this ebook

Why the increasing use of boilerplate is eroding our rights

Boilerplate—the fine-print terms and conditions that we become subject to when we click "I agree" online, rent an apartment, enter an employment contract, sign up for a cellphone carrier, or buy travel tickets—pervades all aspects of our modern lives. On a daily basis, most of us accept boilerplate provisions without realizing that should a dispute arise about a purchased good or service, the nonnegotiable boilerplate terms can deprive us of our right to jury trial and relieve providers of responsibility for harm. Boilerplate is the first comprehensive treatment of the problems posed by the increasing use of these terms, demonstrating how their use has degraded traditional notions of consent, agreement, and contract, and sacrificed core rights whose loss threatens the democratic order.

Margaret Jane Radin examines attempts to justify the use of boilerplate provisions by claiming either that recipients freely consent to them or that economic efficiency demands them, and she finds these justifications wanting. She argues, moreover, that our courts, legislatures, and regulatory agencies have fallen short in their evaluation and oversight of the use of boilerplate clauses. To improve legal evaluation of boilerplate, Radin offers a new analytical framework, one that takes into account the nature of the rights affected, the quality of the recipient's consent, and the extent of the use of these terms. Radin goes on to offer possibilities for new methods of boilerplate evaluation and control, among them the bold suggestion that tort law rather than contract law provides a preferable analysis for some boilerplate schemes. She concludes by discussing positive steps that NGOs, legislators, regulators, courts, and scholars could take to bring about better practices.

LanguageEnglish
Release dateDec 7, 2012
ISBN9781400844838
Boilerplate: The Fine Print, Vanishing Rights, and the Rule of Law
Author

Margaret Jane Radin

Margaret Jane Radin is the Henry King Ransom Professor of Law at the University of Michigan and the William Benjamin Scott and Luna M. Scott Professor of Law, emerita, at Stanford University. Radin is the author of Reinterpreting Property and Contested Commodities.

Related to Boilerplate

Related ebooks

Contracts & Agreements For You

View More

Related articles

Reviews for Boilerplate

Rating: 4 out of 5 stars
4/5

2 ratings0 reviews

What did you think?

Tap to rate

Review must be at least 10 words

    Book preview

    Boilerplate - Margaret Jane Radin

    Boilerplate

    DILBERT © 2011 Scott Adams. Used by permission of UNIVERSAL UCLICK. All rights reserved.

    Boilerplate

    The Fine Print, Vanishing Rights, and the Rule of Law

    Margaret Jane Radin

    Princeton University Press

    Princeton and Oxford

    Copyright © 2013 by Princeton University Press

    Published by Princeton University Press,

    41 William Street, Princeton, New Jersey 08540

    In the United Kingdom: Princeton University Press,

    6 Oxford Street, Woodstock, Oxfordshire OX20 1TW

    press.princeton.edu

    Jacket illustration and design

    by Marcella Engel Roberts

    All Rights Reserved

    Library of Congress Cataloging-in-Publication Data

    Radin, Margaret Jane.

    Boilerplate : the fine print, vanishing rights, and the rule of law / Margaret Jane Radin.

    p. cm.

    Includes index.

    ISBN-13: 978-0-691-15533-3 (cloth : alk. paper)

    ISBN-10: 0-691-15533-X (cloth : alk. paper)

    1. Standardized terms of contract—United States. I. Title.

    KF808.R25 2012

    346.7302’2—dc23

    2012017290

    British Library Cataloging-in-Publication Data is available

    This book has been composed in Sabon LT Std

    Printed on acid-free paper. ∞

    Printed in the United States of America

    1 3 5 7 9 10 8 6 4 2

    In memory of

    C. Edwin Baker

    (1947–2009)

    CONTENTS

    Acknowledgments

    Prologue: World A (Agreement) and World B (Boilerplate)

    Part I. Boilerplate, Consumers’ Rights, and the Rule of Law

    Chapter One • An Overview of Worlds A and B

    Chapter Two • Normative Degradation: Deleting Rights without Consent in the Name of Contract

    Chapter Three • Democratic Degradation: Replacing the Law of the State with the Law of the Firm

    Part II. Boilerplate and Contract Theory: Rationales and Rationalizations

    Chapter Four • A Summary of the Philosophy of Contract: The Theories of World A

    Chapter Five • Can Autonomy Theory (Agreement, Consent) Justify Boilerplate Deletion of Rights?

    Chapter Six • Can Utilitarian-Welfare (Economic) Theory Justify Boilerplate Deletion of Rights?

    Part III. Boilerplate and Contract Remedies: Current Judicial Oversight and Possible Improvements

    Chapter Seven • Evaluating Current Judicial Oversight

    Chapter Eight • Can Current Oversight Be Improved?

    Chapter Nine • Improving Evaluation of Boilerplate: A Proposed Analytical Framework

    Part IV. Escaping Contract: Other Remedial Possibilities

    Chapter Ten • Private Reform Ideas: Possible Market Solutions

    Chapter Eleven • Reconceptualizing (Some) Boilerplate under Tort Law

    Chapter Twelve • Public and Hybrid Regulatory Solutions

    Afterword: What’s Next for Boilerplate?

    Notes

    Index

    ACKNOWLEDGMENTS

    THIS BOOK HAS BEEN a number of years in development. It probably began when I first started teaching contract law at Stanford Law School in the late 1990s, and, of course, noticed that boilerplate fits very uneasily with contract theory. So my first acknowledgment should be to Stanford, and to former Dean Paul Brest, for allowing me to switch from property to contract at that point in my career, and for underwriting the research and writing I did beginning in 2000. Thanks for institutional support of my research is also due to Princeton University, where I was the inaugural Microsoft Fellow in Law and Public Affairs in 2006–2007; at that point I began work on the book that eventually metamorphosed into this one. The institutional support of the University of Michigan from 2007 onward has been indispensable; thanks especially to the Wolfson and Cook funds, and to Dean Evan Caminker and Associate Dean Mark West.

    As it developed, this project benefited from numerous workshops at other schools and the active engagement of workshop participants. Thanks to workshop participants at Duke University, Cornell University, the University of Wisconsin, and the University of Michigan, and to the Georgetown Contract and Promise Workshop organized by Gregory Klass. Thanks to Capital University Law School for inviting me to deliver the 2011 Sullivan Lecture. Very special thanks to the University of Toronto and to Dean Mayo Moran for sponsoring an all-day workshop on a version of this book in March 2011, for which many faculty members read the manuscript and presented their views and critiques. I am grateful for such extraordinary colleagueship. I am also grateful to the Centre For Innovation Law and Policy at the University of Toronto for inviting me to deliver the Grafstein Lecture in March of 2011.

    A great many colleagues have read all or portions of the drafts of this book and significantly improved it. I owe special recognition to the generosity of Michael Trebilcock, who read the entire manuscript in at least two and perhaps three stages of development, and wrote astute comments on many of its pages. For reading through the manuscript and offering helpful critiques and suggestions, thanks also to the ideal colleagueship of Ariel Katz, Abraham Drassinower, Catherine Valcke, Bruce Chapman, Stephen Waddams, Peter Benson, Jennifer Nedelsky, Arthur Ripstein, Brian Langille, Lisa Austin, Ian Lee, Mariana Mota Prado, Simon Stern, Denise Réaume, John Pottow, Bruce Frier, Aditi Bagchi, and Ethan Leib. Thanks to Stephen Poppel, an amateur musician like me, an acquaintance from summer music camp, who read the entire manuscript in an early version and made numerous suggestions for how to make it suitable for nonlawyers to read.

    Thanks to Jay Feinman, Arti Rai, Andrew Gold, and Jeffrey Ferriell for commentary on portions of this project presented at workshops and lectures. I also appreciate suggestions made by Andrew Coan, Kim Krawiec, Bernadette Meyler, Edward Parson, Jill Horwitz, Scott Hershovitz, Robert Hillman, Daniel Schwarcz, Brian Bix, and Daniel Markovits. Special thanks to advocates who offered advice from the field: Paul Bland, John Richard, David Arkush, and Theresa Amato. I am very much indebted to the talented and diligent law students who have worked on this project as research assistants: Stephen Woodcock, Eli Best, Rory Wellever, Bryn R. Pallesen, Aqsa Mahmud, James Ray Mangum, Ankit Bahri, Jennifer Tanaka, John Patrick Clayton, and especially Meera El-Farhan and Shannon Leitner, both eleventh-hour lifesavers. Finally, thanks to Michigan Law Review veterans Adam Teitelbaum and Charles Weikel, who checked the citations on all the notes. Thank you all. I hope I have not forgotten anyone.

    Chuck Myers, my acquisitions editor at Princeton Press, contributed invaluable expertise and critical help. He is very good at what he does! Thanks to Wayland J. Radin for the photos and for help in preparing the manuscript for submission. Finally, thanks to my husband, Phillip Coonce, thanks that I really cannot write with adequate eloquence. Phil’s personal support has been more than the reasonable person could ever have wished for. In addition, he read the manuscript twice from cover to cover, and he improved it significantly with comments ranging from small noodges on almost every page to overarching big questions.

    This book is dedicated to the memory of C. Edwin Baker, my close friend for more than thirty years and my worst (that is, my best) critic for that long. I have no doubt that if Ed were still here, his gracious and tenacious critique would have made this a better book.

    Margaret Jane Radin

    Ann Arbor, Michigan

    December 2011

    PROLOGUE: WORLD A (AGREEMENT) AND WORLD B (BOILERPLATE)

    Agreement, the traditional basis of contract (an invented story):

    Sally says to John, I really like your bicycle. Will you sell it to me for $100? John says, Well, I couldn’t part with it for $100, but how about $125? Sally says, OK, I really do like it, so how about $120? John says, It’s a deal. I’ll go get the bike. Then Sally hands over $120.

    But John never delivers the bike. After John fails to perform his side of the bargain, Sally can bring John to court in a place convenient for her and ask that John be found in breach of contract. If the court finds that John breached a contract with Sally, John will be ordered to compensate Sally. Probably John will be ordered to pay Sally whatever amount she has lost by not receiving the bicycle, which could include not only the amount it would cost her to buy an equivalent bicycle from someone else, but whatever amounts she has lost as a consequence of the broken contract, such as being unable to deliver her packages of handmade chocolates to her customers, and having her customers go to other chocolate sellers.

    Boilerplate, our nonideal contract in practice (stories based on real cases):

    Arbitration Clause: Garrit S., age eleven, a boy who cared deeply about animals, went to Africa with his mother on a fantasy safari vacation. Before it booked the trip, the tour company had Garrit’s mother sign a form. The form waived (cancelled) the right to sue the company for injury to either the mother or the son. Instead, the form said, if there was any complaint against the company, the mother would be limited to arbitration. Such a waiver of legal rights to remedies in court is known as an arbitration clause. (Examples of arbitration clauses appear on pages 111, 116.) A terrible tragedy happened. Hyenas dragged Garrit away from the camp where the tourists were sleeping. The boy was mauled to death. Garrit’s father, who did not sign the pre-tour paperwork, brought suit in court charging the tour company with negligence that caused the death of his son. The company asked the court to halt the suit and instead compel arbitration. This case went all the way to the state supreme court. Garrit’s father was defeated. The state supreme court upheld the trial court’s order to compel arbitration. It held that when the mother signed the paperwork containing the arbitration clause, she signed away her son’s right to jury trial in court as well as her own.¹

    Another Arbitration Clause: Tonya C. was offered a job as manager of a fast-food restaurant at a salary of $7,000 per year. In order to get the job, Tonya was asked to sign some forms. One of the forms contained an arbitration clause that waived Tonya’s right to bring a legal action in court against the franchise owners for any reason, including sexual harassment. Unfortunately, later Tonya did feel she had to bring a sexual harassment claim against her employer. She brought suit under the federal civil rights law that prohibits discrimination on the basis of race, sex, religion, or national origin. The employer filed with the court a motion to dismiss her suit on the ground that the arbitration clause contained in the paperwork Tonya had signed eliminated her right to sue in court. The federal district judge who made the initial decision on Tonya’s claim ruled in her favor. He thought it obvious, despite the arbitration clause in the employer’s form, that a civil rights action based on federal antidiscrimination law belongs in federal court before a jury.

    But on this point the trial judge was overruled by the federal court of appeals. The appellate court was not at all troubled by Tonya’s exclusion from federal court and jury trial. The federal appellate court that reviewed Tonya’s case, along with other federal appellate courts, holds that once an employee (or anyone) is held to have acceded to an arbitration clause, the right to jury trial vanishes.²

    Choice of Forum Clause: Jeffrey K. filed a lawsuit against an Internet service provider on behalf of himself and the class of all other customers of the service provider who were similarly situated. Jeffrey alleged that the service provider had behaved illegally toward its customers by unjustifiably charging an extra fee of $5.00 per month for paying by check instead of by credit card. It would not be worthwhile for one customer to sue for a refund of the $5.00 (multiplied by the number of months he had been a subscriber), and yet the company, if indeed it was behaving in bad faith or unjustly enriching itself at its customers’ expense, was illegally raking in millions of dollars because of the number of customers affected. In a different jurisdiction, two other customers filed a class action against the same Internet service provider, alleging that the service provider had behaved illegally by including in its hourly charges the time it took for customers to view pop-up ads.

    The service provider’s online equivalent of paperwork was its five-page Terms of Service, which subscribers could access by clicking a link, and to which subscribers had to click Agree before proceeding. Jeffrey did not sign anything, but because he became a customer, it could be inferred that he clicked Agree, though of course it was unknown whether he actually clicked the link to the document and read it. The Terms of Service contained a clause saying that lawsuits had to be brought in the state of Virginia. This term is known as a choice of forum clause. Choice of forum clauses are most often coupled with choice of law clauses, in which the parties choose whose law will govern. The state of Virginia does not allow class actions, and this was probably the main reason that the service provider chose Virginia as the only place in which it would allow itself to be sued. Both of these suits were dismissed and the claimants were told to go and sue in Virginia, even though the courts realized that that would be useless.³

    Exculpatory Clause: Michael J., a landscaper, rented a Bobcat truck loader from an equipment company. He paid $185.87 to rent the equipment, and in conjunction with the rental, he was given paperwork to sign. The paperwork included a term stating that the company is not responsible for injuries or damages sustained in the use of these items whether the damages are due to neglect, mechanical failure or any other cause.This term is known as an exculpatory clause, because its purpose is to render the firm not culpable; that is, not legally liable for its harm-causing behavior. (An example of an exculpatory clause appears on page 114.) Michael had asked the advice of the employees of the equipment company before he rented the Bobcat. They told him it was the right equipment for what he wanted to do, which was to transport loose materials to the top of a slope, and they instructed him in how to operate it. Unfortunately, while Michael was using the Bobcat it flipped over. Michael suffered permanent injury to his spinal cord.

    Michael brought suit against the equipment rental company, seeking to hold it liable for causing his injury, because, he alleged, its employees were negligent in their recommendation and instructions. The trial court granted summary judgment for the company, which means that even if everything Michael said were true, he would not have any legal right to hold the company liable. The state supreme court affirmed. Michael had no legal right to hold the company liable even if the company was at fault in causing his injury. The company, the court said, was protected against liability for its own fault by the contract it had had the renter sign.

    What happened to Garrit’s family and the other people in these World B stories was a deletion of legal rights that are otherwise guaranteed by the political order—by the constitution, or by legislation, or by other sources of law. Instead of the set of rights belonging to each of these people under the legal system, they had only the constricted set of legal rights allowed by the firms who delivered paperwork (or its electronic equivalent) to them. Businesses use forms such as those received by the people in these vignettes, and such as most of us receive almost every day, to change the legal infrastructure applicable to us. Businesses use such forms to create their own legal universe. Because we cannot change them, these forms are called boilerplate.*

    All of the clauses in the stories I have recounted above will figure in this book, as will other common clauses occurring in boilerplate. The main project of this book is to consider the following questions: To what extent should firms be permitted to create their own legal universes in this way? What justifications can be brought forward in favor of firms creating their own legal universes? What limits exist on such universe-creation, and what limits should exist? How can such limits best be implemented?

    * According to Wikipedia: The term dates back to the early 1900s and refers to the thick, tough steel sheets used to build steam boilers. From the 1890s onward, printing plates of text for widespread reproduction, such as advertisements or syndicated columns, were cast or stamped in steel (instead of the much softer and less durable lead alloys used otherwise) ready for the printing press and distributed to newspapers around the United States. They came to be known as ‘boilerplates.’ Until the 1950s, thousands of newspapers received and used this kind of boilerplate from the nation’s largest supplier, the Western Newspaper Union. Some companies also sent out press releases as boilerplate so that they had to be printed as written.

    PART I

    Boilerplate, Consumers’ Rights, and the Rule of Law

    CHAPTER ONE

    An Overview of Worlds A and B

    ONCE UPON A TIME, it was thought that contract refers to a bargained-for exchange transaction between two parties who each consent to the exchange. This once-upon-a-time story is the ideal of contract. The story of bargained-for exchange represents contract as it is imagined to be in a world of voluntary agreement, the world I am calling World A (for Agreement). In this book I am referring to contracts, such as the one between Sally and John (in the invented story in the prologue), that actually look like the free exchanges imagined in liberal theory as contracts of World A.* This is still how many people understand contract (with good reason). And it still animates contract theories. Contract is supposed to involve consent by each party to give up something of his or her own to obtain something he or she values more. Sally values the bicycle more than she values her $120; John values $120 more than he values his bicycle. Contract, at least in this paradigm case, is typified by a process of negotiation that results in a bargain satisfactory to both parties. The paradigm case involving negotiation is not the only kind of contract that can be valid under the basic commitment to freedom of contract; but, as we shall see, the elements of the paradigm case involving a bargain and free choice or consent are indispensable.

    Once upon a time, it was also thought that when a contract is broken, there will necessarily be a remedy available to the aggrieved person. If Sally hands over her $120 but John fails to deliver the bicycle, Sally can bring John to court in a place convenient for her, and ask that John be found in breach of contract and have the court order John to make it up to Sally for his breach. Depending on the circumstances, the court will simply order John to refund Sally’s money, or perhaps even to hand over the bicycle. What is important to understand is that the ideal of contract has as an important component the idea that if a contract is breached, there must be the opportunity to seek a remedy. The aggrieved party must have her day in court, and so must the party who allegedly breached. Courts, as an arm of the state, enforce contracts so that all of us may have confidence in dealing with one another. In order for the system of contract to function, there must be a viable avenue for redress of grievances in cases where the bargain fails; otherwise the trust that the ideal of contract imagines would be weakened and perhaps collapse.

    The Stories of the Prologue: Issues for the Basis of Contract

    The Vanishing Right to Jury Trial

    Tonya and Garrit’s father both attempted to bring lawsuits to try their grievances before a jury. By using paperwork to shunt them to arbitration, the companies automatically cancelled their right to a trial before a jury of their peers. Jury trial vanishes in such cases, even if the claimant has not been informed that this will happen—in spite of the fact that most people don’t know what arbitration is and have no idea that their right to jury trial is so fragile. In arbitration, the claimant must appear instead before one or more arbitrators, who are widely believed to be more favorable to businesses. No public record is made of the arbitrators’ decision, and no class actions are permissible.

    The holding in Garrit’s father’s case meant that henceforth in his state, at least, all parents can sign away the remedial rights of their children as well as their own. It also meant that almost all tour companies would include this clause in their pretrip paperwork in the future, as indeed they now do. Companies are also trying the same thing in other states. Although other states are not bound by one state’s holding, judges in other states often take opinions of sister states into account.

    The appellate court in Tonya’s case recited governing law in its jurisdiction suggesting that Tonya could have overturned the effect of the paperwork on her right to try her civil rights claim in federal court before a jury of her peers if she could have proved that she was not able to obtain some other job that did not force her to sign this paperwork. (It seems judges in many jurisdictions actually think that a $7,000-per-year wage earner can look around for another job with less onerous clauses in its paperwork, and perhaps find such an employer if she does look.) Dismissals based on paperwork shunting those with grievances to arbitration are routinely upheld, though in rare cases (as I will describe later in this book) some lucky claimant may be able to overcome the loss of rights accomplished by the paperwork.¹

    It is reasonable to infer that many claimants simply do not try to challenge the paperwork. Most people do not know what an arbitration clause is. Moreover, given the state of the law, lawyers would be remiss if they did not inform a client who is subject to an arbitration clause that very likely he or she should not bother to bring a wrongful death action or a civil rights action in federal court, unless there is something very special about the case.

    Once one business firm finds that courts will enforce dismissal of suits such as these, other businesses will use the same forms. Terms that are favorable to businesses will spread, because they serve the firms’ economic interests. Any term that a court (in a rare case) finds questionable will disappear. All of which means that most people in Tonya’s position would indeed be unlikely to find another employer that did not use the same type of waiver of legal grievance rights that she encountered, or one even more robust. Likewise, most parents wanting to avoid the unhappy position of Garrit’s father in case an unimaginable loss were to befall them would be unlikely to find another tour company that did not impose an arbitration clause.

    Making Redress Remote

    A legislature provides for class actions when it intends for people in its jurisdiction to have the opportunity to seek a remedy, even if the harm to each person is too small to make it worthwhile for that individual to bring suit alone. Class action remedies also are intended to deter companies from reaping large profits by unjustly extracting small overages from large numbers of customers. In the case of Jeffrey K., it is reasonable to infer that the legislature’s intent was thwarted by a choice of forum/choice of law clause that forced the plaintiff into another state.

    Another means whereby a choice of forum clause can effectively deny a remedy to injured parties is by limiting claimants to bringing suit in a jurisdiction that is very far away.² Federal courts are very favorable to choice of forum clauses, based on a famous US Supreme Court case of 1991, Carnival Cruise Lines v. Shute,³ which validated a choice of forum clause forcing injured claimants to bring suit in Florida. In that case, Mrs. Shute was injured on a cruise ship and tried to sue the company in her home state of Washington. The Shutes did not sign anything. The choice of forum clause that prevented Mrs. Shute from suing in Washington was in fine print on the last page of her ticket, which she received after booking the cruise, and which was nonrefundable. Nevertheless, the reasoning upholding the choice of forum clause was based on the assumption that the claimants had willingly accepted the clause. In their enthusiasm for choice of forum clauses, federal courts routinely cite Carnival Cruise as precedent for upholding choice of forum clauses, even in situations where consent by recipients is problematic.

    Escape from Fault

    Michael J., who was injured by the rented Bobcat, was subject to an exculpatory clause. This type of clause waives (cancels) the usual legal rights an injured party would have against a company that was at fault in causing the injury, thus exculpating the company from its own fault. An exculpatory clause goes even further than an arbitration clause, because instead of merely depriving the injured party of a remedy in court, it deprives the injured party of all remedies. Many tour companies, as well as many other proprietors of activities such as camping trips or physical fitness training, are using exculpatory clauses instead of, or in tandem with, arbitration clauses. At this point, parents wanting to escape what happened to Garrit’s father if such a terrible loss were to befall them would be unlikely to find a tour company, or a sports camp, or a training facility, that did not have a clause exculpating itself from liability for any harm suffered by the child while participating in its program, no matter how that harm was caused.

    In some cases a court can hold an exculpatory clause unenforceable (as I will describe later in this book).⁴ In such a case, an injured party would have to litigate, perhaps all the way to a state supreme court or a federal appellate court, before knowing whether he would have the right to hold the company responsible for his injury if he could prove the company was at fault. A litigant could only succeed in achieving this result if he could afford the time and money to litigate or, more likely, if the situation were extreme enough that lawyers who work on a contingency fee basis were willing to take the case. We may safely assume that in cases where the injury is not serious enough (or the injured party is not rich enough), exculpatory clauses will prevail. In general, in situations without the kind of special circumstances that might ultimately persuade a court that the case is exceptional, many people injured through the fault of a business they deal with are precluded by the company’s paperwork from holding the company legally accountable.

    Alternative Legal Universes Created by Forms

    Like the injured parties in the stories of the prologue, most of us are used to receiving paperwork (or its electronic equivalent) during transactions. We are given forms to sign when we rent an automobile or an apartment, and piles of forms to sign when we buy an automobile or a house. Most of us don’t read them, and most of us wouldn’t understand them if we did. We are given forms to sign when we get a job, when we join a gym, when we send our kids to camp. We click I agree to buy products or services on the Internet, after being shown lists of fine-print terms that we don’t read. We receive forms even though we don’t sign them or click I agree, such as the fine-print terms of service interior to websites, or the fine print on everything from parking lot tickets to theater tickets to sports events tickets. Illustrations of some of these commonly used forms are shown on pages 117–119.

    Arbitration clauses, choice of forum/choice of law clauses, and exculpatory clauses, such as those that figured in the stories in the prologue, are common components of the alternative legal universes created by firms. Most readers, I expect, are subject to one or more of them. But there are many other ways in which fine print has the effect of deleting recipients’ legal rights. One common provision limits remedies for losses caused by a defective product or service to the replacement, repair, or reimbursement for the cost of the product itself, thus eliminating damages for injurious consequences of the product’s failure. Another deletes (disclaims) warranty coverage. Another says the firm will continue billing you forever for whatever you have purchased unless you notify it that you wish to terminate. Yet another waives recipients’ user rights in information not protected by the law of intellectual property and otherwise free for public use; and still another waives information privacy rights. (These practices are widespread in the US. Countries other than the US do not make as ubiquitous use of such clauses against consumers. Later in this book I will consider some solutions to boilerplate issues that prevail outside the US.)

    In short, if you are like most US consumers, you enter into contracts daily without knowing it, or at least without being able to do anything about it. The purported contracts come in the form of paperwork that you receive and are asked to sign, or that contain terms supposedly binding without your signature, and sometimes even without their your knowing this is happening. This paperwork is boilerplate, or, less colloquially, standardized form contracts. These are the contracts—the purported contracts—that belong to World B.

    Standardized form contracts, when they are imposed upon consumers, have long been called contracts of adhesion, or take-it-or-leave-it contracts, because the recipient has no choice with regard to the terms.It’s my way or the highway, says the firm to the recipient. Such paperwork is often called boilerplate, because, like the rigid metal used to construct steam boilers in the past, it cannot be altered. I have been calling boilerplate paperwork because paperwork is a neutral term, but you will have noticed that courts most often treat boilerplate as if it were a contract. The law considers boilerplate to be a method of contract formation. World B is the expanding universe of purported contracts that don’t look or act like those of World A.⁶ World B is the world of boilerplate.

    Some of you may belong to firms that impose boilerplate on their customers. But even if you are the CEO, you are subject to boilerplate from other firms, just like everyone else. I myself am subject to many of these clauses. Even though I know more about their legal significance than most people, I can’t do anything about them, so, just like almost everyone else, I don’t read them.⁷ I must, like everyone else, accept them or forego the transaction. I can’t employ a financial manager for my retirement account without accepting an arbitration clause. I can’t use iTunes without clicking I agree to its terms of service. I can’t proceed with an exercise class until I’ve signed a form that exculpates the provider for any injury to me no matter how caused. Once I tried to tell a person presenting paperwork to me that the exculpatory clause would be unenforceable if her studio harmed me intentionally or through gross negligence rather than mere negligence. I took out a pen and offered to emend the clause, but the person presenting the form would not hear of legal niceties. It was take it or leave it.*

    Varieties of World B (Purported) Contracts

    Here is an overview of the varieties of World B contracts we are seeing in practice. (I will stop calling them purported contracts, but please understand that labelling something a contract does not necessarily make it one.)

      1. Standardized Adhesion Contracts of the traditional variety: An example is the parking lot ticket. (See examples on page 117.) It’s a contract of adhesion because either you adhere to it by taking hold of it and then driving your car into the lot, or else you don’t park there. The ticket often says, This contract limits our liability. Read it. Hardly anyone does so. The online analogue is clicking on-screen buttons to signify receipt of contractual terms. By clicking, it says, you are saying that you’ve read the terms and agree to them. It is doubtful that many people are truthful in saying this, though, because very few people read them.*

      2. Offsite Terms: Refers to terms that are a part of standardized adhesion contracts but that are not stated in the document you can see. An example is the airline ticket. It says you are bound by the set of terms that make up the airline’s tariff and that you can find them somewhere else—in the airline’s office, perhaps, or online. Who knows what background legal rights have been given up in favor of the airline?

      3. Shrink-wrap Licenses: So called because they originated with the shrink-wrapped commercial software products that you buy in a box. The idea is that if you break the wrapper you are bound to the terms that are printed below it. By tearing cellophane you have agreed to a bunch of boilerplate.

    A later variant, sometimes called shrink-wrap of the second kind, seeks to bind you to terms that you can’t see until you run the software and look at the first screen. An online analogue to the standard adhesion contract, sometimes called click-wrap, is also considered shrink-wrap of the second kind; it refers to terms that you adhere to by clicking a box onscreen that says I agree. Here the recipient affirms that she has read the terms—but, again, most likely she has not.

      4. Rolling Contracts (also called money now, terms later): Perhaps the earliest example of this variant is the insurance contract. The agent sells you a policy, but

    Enjoying the preview?
    Page 1 of 1