You are on page 1of 22

InternationalOrganization

http://journals.cambridge.org/INO AdditionalservicesforInternationalOrganization: Emailalerts:Clickhere Subscriptions:Clickhere Commercialreprints:Clickhere Termsofuse:Clickhere

ForeignDirectInvestmentandIncomeInequalityinMexico,19902000
NathanM.JensenandGuillermoRosas
InternationalOrganization/Volume61/Issue03/July2007,pp467487 DOI:10.1017/S0020818307070178,Publishedonline:26July2007

Linktothisarticle:http://journals.cambridge.org/abstract_S0020818307070178 Howtocitethisarticle: NathanM.JensenandGuillermoRosas(2007).ForeignDirectInvestmentandIncomeInequalityinMexico,19902000. InternationalOrganization,61,pp467487doi:10.1017/S0020818307070178 RequestPermissions:Clickhere

Downloadedfromhttp://journals.cambridge.org/INO,IPaddress:148.205.107.134on30Aug2012

Foreign Direct Investment and Income Inequality in Mexico, 1990 2000


Nathan M+ Jensen and Guillermo Rosas

Abstract In this article we explore the relationship between the investments of multinational corporations ~foreign direct investment! and income inequality in Mexico+ We argue that Mexicos liberalization of foreign direct investment ~FDI! inows in the 1990s provides a natural experiment to test how FDI affects income inequality in a middle-income country+ We use an instrumental variables approach as our identication strategy to mitigate problems of endogeneity and omitted variable bias+ In an empirical test of the determinants of changes in income inequality from 1990 to 2000, we nd that increased FDI inows are associated with a decrease in income inequality within Mexicos thirty-two states+

Globalization has distributional consequences both within and across societies+ In the areas of international trade and immigration, theoretical and empirical research has explored how the movement of goods and people affect distributions of income+ Although considerable debate remains, existing economic models provide falsiable hypotheses on how trade and migration affect income distributions+ Surprisingly, despite the vast literature on multinational corporations ~MNCs! and their investments and the increasing activity of countries in attempting to woo foreign investment, little research has explored the impact of foreign direct investment ~FDI! on income inequality+ In this article we argue that theoretical predictions regarding the effect of FDI on income distribution within a country are muddled+ Economic models of FDI, usually focused on decisions at the rm level in response to market imperfections, provide competing predictions of the relationship between FDI and income inequality+ We believe that measuring the net impact of FDI on income inequality becomes

The authors would like to thank Lawrence Broz, John Freeman, Matt Gabel, Geoff Garrett, Quan Li, Eddy Malesky, Layna Mosley, Katie Ridgeway, Pablo Pinto, John Stringer, and Andy Sobel for comments and suggestions+ Jacob Gerber and Mariana Medina provided excellent research assistance+ Thanks also to Patricio Aroca Gonzalez for generously providing us with his data+ We acknowledge the nancial support of the Weidenbaum Center on the Economy, Government, and Public Policy+ Nate Jensens contribution to this article was written as a Global Fellow at UCLAs International Institute+ International Organization 61, Summer 2007, pp+ 46787 2007 by The IO Foundation+

DOI: 10+10170S0020818307070178

468

International Organization

an empirical question, but one that has to be approached carefully, because potential issues of reverse causality, selection bias, and omitted variable bias in studies of FDI can lead to spurious results+ We focus on the liberalization of capital ows in Mexico from 1990 to 2000 and on how the ensuing surge of multinational investments changed state-level income inequality+ Thus, we can compare Mexico prior to FDI to Mexico after FDI and assess the effects on the distribution of income of such capital inows+ More importantly, the decision of most U+S+ MNCs to locate close to one of the six main border routes linking the United States and Mexico also provides spatial variation that allows us to explore how levels of income inequality changed in Mexican states that attracted massive amounts of FDI in contrast with Mexican states that attracted little FDI+ This geographic component of FDI provides us with a natural experiment: using instrumental variables estimation, with distance to the border as a truly exogenous variable, we nd that states that attracted higher levels of FDI enjoyed lesser income inequality relative to states with less FDI+ We believe this strategy mitigates the serious problem of omitted variable bias+ We present our argument as follows+ In the next section, we review the extant literature on the international determinants of inequality, especially arguments regarding the effect of FDI on income inequality+ In the second section, we point to potential problems of endogeneity that plague previous ndings in the literature+ We lay out an appropriate research design and focus the discussion of FDI and income inequality on the case of Mexico, a middle-income economy that beneted from increased FDI ows during the 1990s+ We then describe the construction of empirical indicators and carry out estimation of a model of FDI and income inequality in the third and fourth sections+ We conclude in the last section by pointing out avenues for further research+

Theory
The topic of income inequality has received increasing attention within the elds of international and comparative political economy+ For starters, a lively debate currently rages over whether patterns of economic inequality within and across nations have changed at all during the past two decades, and if so, whether these changes can be attributed to globalization+1 Although a full literature review of the determinants of income inequality is beyond the scope of this article, we nd it useful to summarize some of the hypothesized causal connections between globalization and economic inequality+ Following Bradley and colleagues, we distinguish arguments as either emphasizing state institutions or global markets as the main forces driving income inequality+2

1+ See Firebaugh 1999; Milanovic 2005; Sala-i-Martin 2002; and Wade 2001+ 2+ Bradley et al+ 2003+

Foreign Investment and Income Inequality in Mexico

469

Many scholars believe that economic distribution is ultimately shaped by domestic factors such as labor market organization and political institutions, even if changes in international market conditions are the main cause of demands for redistribution+ At least in countries within the Organization for Economic Cooperation and Development ~OECD!, where this research program has made most inroads, studies argue that patterns of income inequality are determined by political demands for redistribution and safety nets, and by institutions that regulate the supply of public policy, such as party system organization+ In particular, several authors have recently argued that similar market pressures derived from globalization will translate into different public policies and, presumably, into different patterns of income inequality+3 The capacity of political parties to achieve more egalitarian distributions of disposable income seems to be constrained by patterns of labor market organization+ For example, some research suggests that highly unionized labor markets and institutions conducive to centralized wage bargaining allow leftist parties to achieve more egalitarian distributions of opportunity through nontargeted social programs+4 Alternatively, governments can directly redistribute income through progressive income transfer policies, although it is a point of debate whether such policies are possible at all under globalization+5 Finally, government policy can affect individual decisions regarding investment in acquiring different types of skills+6 Most of these studies adopt a decidedly cross-national perspective to explore variation in domestic political institutions as a determinant of distributive outcomes+ In contrast, theoretical arguments that emphasize the role of global markets tend to emphasize similarities across countries+ For example, Rodrik argues that globalization leads not only to a shift in demand but also increases the elasticity of demand for labor+ As capital can credibly threaten to relocate in a global economy, the bargaining power of labor is greatly diminished, presumably leading to wage concessions across countries+7 Other market-based theories explore how trade or capital mobility can lead to shifts in the demand for different factors of production+ In this vein, scholars suggest that whether international trade has a positive or negative effect on the demand for unskilled labor depends on a countrys comparative advantage vis--vis trading partners+8 Among theorists that build on the premise of comparative advantage, the common understanding is that while the liberalization of trade and capital ows provides a net gain for all countries, the forces of globalization generate winners and losers within the borders of nation-states+ For example, in one of the classic trade

3+ See Boix 1998; Garrett 1998; and Iversen and Cusack 2000+ 4+ See Beramendi and Cusack 2004; Esping-Andersen 1990; Garrett 1998; Kenworthy and Pontusson 2005; Pontusson, Rueda, and Way 2002; and Wallerstein 1999+ 5+ See Bradley et al+ 2003; Moene and Wallerstein 2001; Oatley 1999; and Swank 2002+ 6+ Iversen and Soskice 2001+ 7+ Rodrik 1997+ 8+ See Wood 1994; and Freeman 1995+

470

International Organization

models, Stolper and Samuelson argue that free trade would raise the incomes of the abundant factors of production and lower the returns to the scarce factors of production+9 Assuming a simple model with only two factors of production, capital and labor, there are clear distributional implications from free trade+ In countries such as the United States that have large endowments of capital, free trade will increase the returns to capital ~prots!, while decreasing the returns to labor ~wages!+ Conversely, in developing countries with large endowments of labor relative to capital, free trade will increase wages and decrease prots+ This leads to clear predictions on how trade affects income inequality according to a countrys factor endowments+10 In advanced industrialized countries ~countries rich in capital!, a liberalization of trade should increase income inequality by increasing the returns of capital and decreasing the returns to labor+ Conversely, in the developing countries, trade liberalization should decrease income inequality by increasing the returns to labor and decreasing the returns to capital+ A second broad research agenda focuses on differences between various types of labor, particularly skilled versus unskilled, and how trade affects income inequality+ A number of scholars have argued that globalization has led to an increased premium for skilled labor, thus suggesting that trade liberalization decreases the returns to low-skilled labor and increases the returns to high-skilled labor+ These arguments became familiar to noneconomists in the recent debate in the United States over the impact of North American Free Trade Agreement ~NAFTA! on U+S+ workers+ Although debate remains over the distributional impact of trade, economic models provide us with theoretical tools to generate hypotheses regarding the effects of trade on income inequality+ While the vast literature on the link between income inequality and trade provides guidance on how globalization affects income inequality, one has to tread carefully in applying these insights to the study of FDI+ FDI blossomed as a eld of study when Hymer identied the differences between FDI and other types of nancial capital+11 Hymer argued that FDI is driven by market imperfections, rather than by factor endowments or differences in rates of return across borders+ Foreign rms have advantages over domestic rms, and these foreign rms choose to locate in a country to turn this advantage into prots, rather than export their goods or services or license domestic rms to make the product for the MNC+ One of the main explanations for FDI is that MNCs possess intangible assets that are not easily transferred across borders+12 Thus, MNCs often look quite different from domestic rms, employing more skilled workers and using more advanced technologies+ One fairly consistent nd-

9+ Stolper and Samuelson 1941+ 10+ Wood 1994+ 11+ Hymer 1976+ See also Aliber 1971; Caves 1971; Dunning 1971, 1977, and 1981; and Kindleberger 1969+ 12+ Markusen 1995+

Foreign Investment and Income Inequality in Mexico

471

ing within the FDI literature is that MNCs pay a wage premium over local rms+13 Part of this result is attributed to MNCs locating in industries and in urban areas that have higher median wages than the national median wage+14 Yet, even after controlling for factors that tend to overstate the MNC wage premium, MNCs still pay considerably higher wages than local rms+15 This link between MNCs and the increased demand for skilled workers has been generally supported in the empirical literature on the impact of FDI, although most of this literature is focused on the developed economies+16 Most relevant for this study, Feenstra and Hanson nd that FDI into Mexico leads to increased wages of skilled workers relative to unskilled workers and thus probably increases income inequality+17 What does this mean for the relationship between FDI and levels of income inequality? We emphasize two mechanisms through which MNCs may affect income distribution within a country+ First, MNCs bring capital into the country, decreasing the total returns to capital and increasing the returns to labor+ Thus, foreign capital competes with domestic capital for domestic workers, driving up wages and decreasing the protability of domestic rms+ This effect would speed up convergence of the incomes of labor relative to capital, decreasing income inequality+ Second, MNCs pay a wage premium over domestic rms+ If MNCs pay a wage premium for skilled workers, this would lead to an increase in the income differential between skilled and unskilled workers but also to diminished income disparity between skilled workers and holders of capital+ Conversely, if MNCs would hire unskilled workers and pay a wage premium for them, FDI would decrease income inequality by raising the incomes of workers that are most likely at the bottom of the income distribution+ The complex relationship between FDI and income inequality becomes clear from an overview of the theoretical determinants of FDI: for the most advanced countries, such as the United States, Japan, or Europe, much of the cross-border FDI consists of mergers and acquisitions+ For example, Europes Daimler-Benz purchase of Chrysler led to a massive ow of FDI into the United States; yet, we have little theoretical insight into how this affected income inequality in the United States+ Perhaps more perplexing is the inow of Japanese FDI into the U+S+ auto sector+ Most scholars argue that Japanese auto manufacturers chose to jump U+S+ tariffs on imported automobiles and build autos in the United States+ What was the impact of this FDI on income inequality in the United States? Clearly the success of Japanese auto producers has had some impact on Detroit, where erce competition has cost the city numerous highly paid auto production jobs+ In contrast, foreign car companies have built production facilities that generate highpaying jobs in the Midwest, West, and South+ Most of these foreign plants are not

13+ 14+ 15+ 16+ 17+

See Moran 1998+ See Klein, Aaron, and Hadjimichael 2001; and Moran 1998+ See Te Velde 2003, for a review of the literature+ See Hanson 2004; and Te Velde 2003+ Feenstra and Hanson 1997+

472

International Organization

unionized and pay lower wages than the unionized plants of the Big Three U+S+ car manufacturers+ These foreign car facilities are generally located in poor areas of the United States, generating employment and wage growth, especially in the South+ In this article we attempt to circumvent the existing empirical pitfalls in the study of links between FDI and income inequality by focusing on a natural experiment in a middle-income country+ We focus on the liberalization of capital inows into Mexico in the mid-1990s to test the impact of FDI on income inequality+ In the following section we discuss the case+

Research Design
Few studies have directly tested the impact of FDI ows on income inequality+ One recent study by Reuveny and Li tests the impact of FDI on income inequality in sixty-nine countries from 196095+18 They nd that although democracy and trade decrease income inequality, FDI ows increase the level of income inequality+ Similarly, Alderson and Nielsen nd a positive association between the stock of FDI and income inequality in an unbalanced panel of eighty-eight countries observed at different points in time between 1969 and 1994+19 A complete review of the literature on FDI and income inequality is beyond the scope of this article, yet we believe that these studies are representative of the broader literature+20 Although we believe it is important to address cross-national patterns of domestic income inequality, we are slightly skeptical about the ability to test the causal link between FDI and the distribution of income with this type of research design+ In this design, FDI is generally treated as an exogenous factor+ Consider, however, the case of China, which received little FDI in 1960 but is the leading FDI recipient in recent years and where income inequality has arguably increased during the past decade+ We believe that other factors, such as economic liberalization, have an equally plausible claim to explain the increase in income inequality in China+ More formally, we can think of studies exploring the link between income inequality and FDI as potentially suffering from omitted variable bias, selection bias, and reverse causation+ The issue of omitted variable bias is the most transparent in the study of FDI+ FDI decisions occur at the rm level, yet most scholars study FDI ows with models that look at country-level variables measured annually+ This is damning if omitted variables are correlated with the error term+ We believe that this bias is especially problematic in countries that enact economic

18+ Reuveny and Li 2003+ 19+ Alderson and Nielsen 1999+ 20+ See Te Velde 2003, for a review of the literature on FDI and income inequality in Latin America+ See also World Bank 2006, for a broad overview on the relationship between globalization and income inequality+

Foreign Investment and Income Inequality in Mexico

473

reform in a bundle, liberalizing FDI laws at the same time that they privatize stateowned enterprises and implement sweeping trade reforms+21 Unless appropriate indicators are included in the model specication, any ndings on the relationship between FDI and income inequality may be capturing the impact of omitted variables on changing patterns of income inequality+ Selection bias can also lead to spurious results on the study of FDI and income inequality+ For example, an excellent study by Moran nds that MNCs, even in the most labor-intensive industries, tend to locate their operations near pools of highly trained labor+22 Firms in the textile industry often invest near or in major cities in countries that have low national-level wages and a pool of educated labor+ At the same time, there is an increasing skill premium generated by technological change according to recent economic studies+23 Thus, countries with large pools of both high- and low-skilled labor are most likely the countries that will have the most growth in wage inequality anyway, independent of FDI+ Finally, there is an argument for the possibility of reverse causation+ Firms could be purposely locating in countries with high or low levels of income inequality+ The argument for rms purposely investing in countries with high-income inequality is most probable in the textile or footwear industry+ In numerous countries, governments have attracted these labor-intensive operations to export-processing zones+24 In many cases, governments provide exceptions for national labor laws, including the right to collective bargaining, unions, and strikes+ Even more problematic is the possibility that rms avoid investments in countries with high levels of income inequality+ As outlined by Alesina and Perotti, higher levels of income inequality can threaten social stability and reduce levels of domestic investment+25 According to Jensen, investors, political risk insurers, and plant location consultants understand that high levels of income inequality can lead to social conict or the targeting of foreign rms for redistributive policies+ Income inequality is a risk for rms, and this risk leads to lower levels of FDI+26 Thus, studies of the link between FDI and income inequality that fail to control for the possibility of reverse causation may nd a spurious relationship between higher levels of FDI and lower levels of income inequality+ In this article we explore how FDI affects income inequality within a single country+ To begin with, this strategy allows us to more precisely specify our theoretical intuitions on how FDI will affect wages+ We focus on the impact of FDI inows on income inequality in Mexico during the 1990s+ Mexico underwent a rapid process of liberalization starting with the Salinas administration in 1988, a

21+ See Biglaiser and DeRouen 2006; and Korzeniewicz and Smith 2000, for emphasis on Latin America+ 22+ Moran 2002+ 23+ Wood 1994+ See also Tuman and Emmert 2004+ 24+ Moran 2002+ 25+ Alesina and Perotti 1996+ 26+ Jensen 2003 and 2006+

474

International Organization

process that eventually led to the negotiation and implementation of NAFTA+27 During this period of liberalization Mexico experienced a dramatic increase in FDI inows+ We illustrate this phenomenon in Figure 1+ Note the staggering increase in FDI inows, both as a proportion of gross domestic product ~Panel A! and in dollar terms ~Panel B!, after the 1989 liberalization of controls on capital ows and particularly after the 1994 implementation of NAFTA+ The buildup of FDI throughout the 1990s provides us with temporal variation to explore how the increase in FDI affected the distribution of income in Mexico from 1990 to 2000+ Furthermore, we can exploit the regional variation in FDI to address its effect on income inequality+ As in the example of China given earlier, Mexico carried out major economic reforms, including liberalization of the nancial sector, throughout the 1990s+ National changes in income inequality from 1990 to 2000 could be easily attributed to any of several national-level policy changes or even to statelevel characteristics+ Yet, the interesting regional pattern of FDI inows gives us leverage to address the issue of endogeneity of our FDI indicator+ Most of the FDI owing into Mexico located either in the states bordering the United States or in Mexico City ~see Figure 2!+28 It would be difcult to argue that this pattern of investment close to the U+S+ border was conditional on higher levels of education, better infrastructure, cleaner governance, or many of the other state-level factors we would normally associate with a good investment environment+ Instead, these decisions were largely carried out based on an exogenous factor, namely, the distance from one of the six major routes linking Mexico to the United States+ Consistent with the typical maquila pattern of FDI, U+S+ rms located in Mexico to take advantage of lower labor costs and to export nished or intermediate products back into the United States+ Spatial variation provides leverage to evaluate how FDI inows affected income inequality within Mexico+ Unlike other studies that ignore the endogeneity of FDI ows, we argue that while the timing of FDI was clearly caused by factors such as Mexican trade and capital liberalizations, the actual location of FDI was determined by an exogenous geographic factor+ States that border the United States received lots of FDI while the rest of Mexico, bar Mexico City, received little FDI+ Comparing the changing pattern of income inequality in states close to the border as opposed to other states in Mexico provides us with a natural experiment+ By using the distance from U+S+ border crossing points as an instrument explaining the decision of MNCs to invest into different Mexican states, we can circumvent the pitfalls of endogeneity we identied above and more persuasively estimate the effect of FDI on income inequality+ Distance to the border is an ideal instrument, as it is highly correlated with FDI, but there is no theoretical reason to believe

27+ See Hanson 2005b+ 28+ After controlling for population density, this pattern becomes even more accentuated+ Average per capita annual ows of FDI from 1994 to 2000 amount to US $1,130 along the six border states ~Baja California, Sonora, Chihuahua, Coahuila, Nuevo Len, Tamaulipas!, but only US $311 in the rest of the country ~and even this gure is exaggerated by inclusion of Mexico City!+

Foreign Investment and Income Inequality in Mexico

475

FIGURE 1.

FDI over time

that it is associated with unobserved variables omitted from the model+ We build an instrumental variable model using the minimum distance from one of the six major land routes between the United States and Mexico as an instrument for statelevel FDI+ We then estimate the changing pattern of income inequality that fol-

476

International Organization

FIGURE 2.

Territorial distribution of FDI stock, 2000

lows from the decision of foreign rms to invest in Mexican states+ We minimize potential concerns about reverse causation by measuring inequality in 1990, four years before our rst available measure of FDI+ We then gauge the effects of FDI ows on income inequality in 2000+ What are our predictions about the impact of FDI on income inequality in Mexico? As argued before, the relevant literature has explored the differential between skilled and unskilled labor as one causal mechanism linking FDI to inequality+ Feenstra and Hanson nd that FDI increased the relative demand for skilled workers and was a driver of income inequality from 197588+29 Aitken, Harrison, and Lipsey nd that foreign rms pay a 21+5 percent wage premium for skilled workers and only a 3+3 percent wage premium for unskilled workers+30 Finally, most relevant for this study, Hanson explores the relationship between the wages of working males in states with most exposure to trade and investments ~border states! with those of states with low exposure+31 Hanson nds that though the Mexican peso crisis led to decreasing wages in all regions, the low exposure states were hit much harder+ Also, the distributions of income shifted more to the right in the high exposure states relative to the low exposure states+ These results are mostly driven by a collapse in the incomes of employed males in the lower income states+

29+ Feenstra and Hanson 1997+ 30+ Aitken, Harrison, and Lipsey 1996+ 31+ Hanson 2005a+

Foreign Investment and Income Inequality in Mexico

477

While these studies provide important ndings, they focus on explaining the widening gap between skilled and unskilled labor+ Our article is concerned with the broader question of how FDI affects income inequality, which is also driven by the relative returns to capital and labor, along with wage differentials within the broad categories of skilled and unskilled labor+ This is not a minor point+ The relative scarcity of skilled workers in Mexico makes us skeptical about the impact of changing skilled-labor wages on patterns of income inequality+ According to the 2000 International Labour Organization ~ILO! survey of Mexico, a little more than 6 percent of workers in the country are classied as professional or technical workers+32 Even though this gure clearly does not include all skilled workers, the fact that the vast majority of workers are classied as unskilled means that the wage differential between skilled and unskilled workers is probably only a minor determinant of income inequality in Mexico+33 Moreover, MNCs also pay a wage premium for unskilled workers, as stated earlier+ We believe instead that the major impact of MNCs will be similar to what Stolper and Samuelson would predict+34 Increased FDI into Mexico will raise the demand for skilled and unskilled workers alike+ Since, as we argued above, most FDI goes into regions close to the border, we expect reductions in income inequality produced by wage increases for unskilled and semi-skilled workers along the northern states+ If workers were perfectly mobile within Mexico, we would expect national wages for low- and semi-skilled workers to increase, leading to a leveling of income inequality across the whole country+ Yet, as we know, workers are never perfectly mobile even in the most advanced industrialized economies+ In Mexico, there is evidence that the lower skilled are signicantly less mobile both internally ~betweenstates migration! and externally ~migration to the United States!+35 If workers are imperfectly mobile, regional wage differences can arise in relation to the location of foreign rms+ Thus, we believe that the major impact of FDI in Mexico is a changing pattern of income inequality within regions in Mexico+ In the states with the most FDI, largely determined by geography, we expect a decrease in levels of income inequality relative to the states with least FDI+ Figure 3 provides a rst glimpse at the changing patterns of income inequality from 1990 to 2000+ Note that although some states along the U+S+ border have seen improvements in the distribution of income, it is by no means obvious that FDI ~as portrayed in Figure 2! is driving the process+

32+ Lpez-Acevedo, Tinajero, and Rubio 2005 analyze rm-level 2001 data for Mexico and nd that 71 percent of employees had no more than lower secondary school education+ 33+ A secondary issue is that most research focuses on the wage differences between low-skilled and high-skilled workers+ One of the motivations for attracting FDI is for the prospects of skill upgrading+ We can imagine a situation where a widening wage difference between skilled and unskilled labor could still lead to a leveling of income inequality if some of the unskilled workers become skilled workers+ 34+ Stolper and Samuelson 1941+ 35+ Stark and Taylor 1991+ This is the same assumption used by Hanson 2005a+

478

International Organization

FIGURE 3.

Territorial distribution of changes in state Gini indices, 19902000

Income Inequality and Foreign Direct Investment Data


To test our claim that FDI improves income distribution, we must construct subnational measures of income inequality and FDI+ In this section, we operationalize FDI and state-level inequality+ The income inequality indices are based on information from the 1990 and 2000 Mexican national census; census data are publicly available through the Instituto Nacional de Estadstica, Geografa e Informtica ~INEGI!+36 The actual calculation of Gini indices is based on novel methods proposed by Milanovic and Abounoori and McCloughan+37 These methods allow construction of unbiased Gini coefcients from grouped income data, such as is available from the Mexican census+38 To construct our measures of

36+ See ^www+inegi+gob+mx&+ Accessed 16 March 2007+ 37+ See Abounoori and McCloughan 2003; and Milanovic 1994+ These data are detailed in Rosas 2006+ 38+ INEGI aggregates the census information at the municipal level and posts frequencies by income group for the purpose of public dissemination+ The data may consider a family to be rich if it reports high income without consideration of family size+ Since poorer, rural families tend to be larger, the extent of income inequality is underestimated; see Corts 2003, 142+ A more appropriate measure should consider per capita income, but even INEGI routinely reports inequality gures that are not corrected by family size, see Corts and Rubalcava 1995; and Corts 2003+

Foreign Investment and Income Inequality in Mexico

479

inequality, we have had to impose two minor restrictions to guarantee comparability between the 1990 and 2000 census+ First, the 1990 census considers individuals twelve years of age or older, whereas the 2000 version refers to the economically active population ~individuals aged twelve years or older, excluding students, housewives, and retirees!+ For purposes of comparison, we consider the economically active population to comprise all individuals twelve years of age or older+ Second, nonrespondents total about 5 percent of all individuals in the census+ We distributed nonrespondents into the other categories, according to the relative frequency of each category in each municipality+ To measure the amount of FDI at the state level, we draw on two data sources+ Patricio Aroca Gonzalez generously provided his data on state-level FDI, which we have updated with information from the Direccin General de Inversin Extranjera of the Mexican Ministry of the Economy+39 This data measures the dollar amount of FDI registered in any given Mexican state+ One problem in these data, pointed out by Aroca Gonzalez and Maloney, is that many rms register their investments in Mexico City, yet their operations are often located in another state ~usually border states!+40 Aroca Gonzalez and Maloney use an alternative measure of FDI ~although this measure is not collected for all states! and nd that the results are consistent across FDI measures after including a dummy variable for Mexico City+ Consequently, we operationalize FDI as the average dollar value of per capita FDI ows during the period 19932000+41

Empirical Results
To explore the relationship between FDI and the distribution of income, we rst estimate a cross-sectional ordinary least squares ~OLS! regression to estimate the impact of inows of FDI in the thirty-two Mexican states on levels of income inequality+ Using the OLS results as a benchmark, we then estimate an instrumental variable two-stage least squares ~IV-2SLS! regression model of the following form: Gini2000
* FDI19932000

b0 g0

* b1 FDI19932000

b2 Gini1990

b3 GSPpc1990 g3 Education

~1!

g1 Gini1990 g4 Distance

g2 GSPpc1990

~2!

39+ Data are available at ^http:00www+economia+gob+mx0?P 1178&, accessed 16 March 2007+ 40+ Aroca Gonzalez and Maloney 2005+ 41+ FDI data are not available at the state level prior to 1993+ Given that the bulk of FDI entered the Mexican economy after the implementation of NAFTA, we do not have reason to believe that this will bias our results+

480

International Organization

TABLE 1.

Summary statistics

Variable gini 1990 gini 2000 lgdppc lfdi Minimum distance to border crossing points ~in miles! Education ~schooling average in years for 2000!

Mean 0+479 0+471 2+528 2+541 441+3 7+441

Standard deviation 0+045 0+036 0+428 1+969 171+1 0+898

Minimum 0+405 0+417 1+812 2+843 15+02 5+600

Maximum 0+579 0+568 3+589 6+067 749+7 9+700

Thus, we model the level of income inequality in each Mexican state in 2000 as a function of the level of income inequality in 1990, per capita gross state product in 1990, and an instrument for ~log! average FDI inows from 19932000 * ~FDI19932000 !, namely, tted values of a regression of FDI on excluded instrumentsdistance to the border and education ~average years of schooling! and all other second-stage independent variables as included instruments+42 Strictly speaking, our model is overidentied through use of education as a second excluded instrument; in this case, overidentication is necessary to ensure that we can appropriately test the assumption of no correlation between instrument and error process+43 We provide summary statistics for all our indicators in Table 1+ We present our models based on state-level data in Table 2+ Column ~1! of the table suggests that increased levels of FDI are associated with a decrease in income inequality in an OLS model+ As argued earlier, many MNCs register their operations in Mexico City, although their production operations are located near the border+ As a check on the robustness of our results, we estimate the impact of FDI inows on income inequality in column ~2! of the table, dropping Mexico City+ Our substantive results remain unchanged+ As highlighted earlier, FDI ows may be endogenous, making the OLS estimates inefcient, biased, and inconsistent+ Foreign investors may select production locations based on factors such as the quality of infrastructure or prevailing state-level wages+ To mitigate these endogeneity concerns, we present in column ~3! of Table 2 the results of an IV-2SLS regression using the minimum distance from one of the six major border crossings and the total number of years of education as instruments for FDI+ IV regressions have become relatively common in political science, but it is important to note that this method is not a panacea for

42+ Strictly speaking, the dependent variable is bounded above ~1! and below ~0!+ However, the cross-state distribution of the Gini indices is unimodal, and even the maximum ~0+58! and minimum ~0+41! values are so far from the theoretical bounds that we are comfortable modeling E~Y6X! as a linear function of effect parameters, as in OLS or 2SLS+ 43+ Baum, Schaffer, and Stillman 2003+

Foreign Investment and Income Inequality in Mexico

481

TABLE 2.

State-level results

OLS Constant gini 1990 lgdppc lfdi DF included N R2 F Hansen J Excluded instruments F-test 0+139* ~1+92! 0+724*** ~5+87! 0+010 ~0+47! 0+010** ~ 2+13! Yes 32 0+79 49+82

OLS (excluding Mexico City) 0+182** ~2+35! 0+669*** ~5+55! 0+003 ~0+901! 0+011** ~ 2+11! No 31 0+80 51+54

IV 0+172** ~2+19! 0+586*** ~3+33! 0+030 ~1+31! 0+018** ~ 2+78! Yes 32 0+76 31+65 2+425 7+90***

IV (excluding Mexico City) 0+229*** ~2+99! 0+495*** ~2+81! 0+026 ~1+31! 0+019*** ~ 3+18! No 31 0+76 31+18 1+116 7+21***

Note: All regressions estimated with robust ~Huber-White! standard errors ~t-statistics in parentheses!+ OLS ordinary least squares+ IV instrumental variable two-stage least squares+ *** p , 0+01 ~two-tailed test!; ** p , 0+05; * p , 0+10+

solving issues of endogeneity+ For our instrument to be valid, the minimum distance to the U+S+ border crossing and the level of education must be correlated with FDI inows, and they must not be correlated with the error term in equation ~1!+ For our IV specications, we include F-tests for excluded instruments and tests of overidentication using Hansens J-statistic+ In our IV estimates, the F-test for excluded instruments is statistically signicant at the 0+01 level, indicating that we have valid instruments for the level of FDI inows+ Also, Hansens J-statistic is not statistically signicant at even the 0+1 level, indicating that we cannot reject the null that our regressions are appropriately overidentied+44 The results of the IV regressions, both including and excluding Mexico City, are similar to the OLS regressions, although the magnitude of the impact is substantially increased when compared to the OLS benchmark results+ The impact of FDI on income inequality is negative, meaning that exposure to FDI leads to decreasing levels of income inequality+ Based on coefcients from the IV-2SLS specication, we nd that a two standard deviation increase in FDI leads to a 2+4 standard deviation decrease in income inequality from 1990 to 2000+ Figure 4 illustrates uncertainty regarding the effect of FDI on income inequality by displaying a 95 percent condence interval around expected values+ Despite large estimation

44+ Ibid+

482

International Organization

FIGURE 4.

Expected Gini index conditional on per capita FDI (95% condence

interval) uncertainty caused by a relatively small set of observations ~thirty-two states!, we still nd that increases in FDI are associated with large reductions in levels of income inequality, all else constant+ Although our study focuses on whether or not FDI affects the distribution of income, it is important to consider the causal mechanism linking FDI and income inequality+ One possible explanation is that FDI has led to a collapse in the incomes of domestic capital in the border states, essentially leveling income inequality by reducing the income of individuals at the higher end of the income distribution+ Yet, Hanson nds that it is the states with low exposure to FDI where the incomes of workers fell by 10 percent and wage poverty increased 7 percent relative to high FDI states after the Mexican peso crisis+45 Thus, FDI in Mexico has actually led to lower levels of income inequality in the northern states, at the same time that incomes were becoming extremely unequal in the low-exposure states+

45+ Hanson 2005a+

Foreign Investment and Income Inequality in Mexico

483

TABLE 3.

Breakdown by foreign direct investment (FDI) and income category

Average change (% points) in proportions of families in each income group, 19902000 (1) 00.5 High FDI Low FDI 0+024 ~0+019! 0+017 ~0+030! (2) 0.5 to 1 0+038 ~0+032! 0+034 ~0+029! (3) 1 to 2 0+071 ~0+050! 0+039 ~0+038! (4) 2 to 3 0+026 ~0+044! 0+008 ~0+037! (5) 3 to 5 0+053 ~0+025! 0+045 ~0+022! (6) 5 to 10 0+035 ~0+016! 0+028 ~0+010! (7) 10 0+018 ~0+010! 0+011 ~0+009!

Notes: High FDI states are those with above average FDI: Aguascalientes, Baja California Norte, Baja California Sur, Coahuila, Colima, Chihuahua, DF, Jalisco, Estado de Mxico, Morelos, Nuevo Len, Puebla, Quretaro, Quintana Roo, San Luis Potos, Sonora, Tamaulipas+

Though we cannot speak directly to the issue of income differentials between 1990 and 2000, our data allow us to compare growth in the number of families in different income categories+ Table 3 offers a breakdown of change in the percentage of families within each or our seven income categories in high and low FDI states+ First, it does not seem to be the case that diminished inequality is driven by a collapse in the number of families at the upper end of the income distribution+ Second, both types of states show increases in the number of families at the upper tail of the distribution and decreases in the lower categories+ However, decreases in the number of poor families and increases in the number of well-off families seem to be more pronounced among high FDI states+ We caution the reader that in our small sample only the numbers in income category ~3! ~that is, those reporting income of one to two minimum wages! are statistically different across FDI categories at the 95 percent level+ Though we cannot conrm which mechanism is most important in tying FDI to diminished income inequality, evidence is consistent with the claim that unskilled workers are beneting the most from increased FDI, at least if we consider that unskilled workers are more common in category ~3!+ We believe this evidence, specically in the context of a natural experiment, illustrates that FDI ows can lead to an increase in the incomes of workers and a leveling of income inequality within states+

Conclusions
In this article we explore the relationship between inows of foreign direct investment and changing patterns of income inequality in Mexico from 19902000+ Using geographic proximity to major border crossings with the United States as an

484

International Organization

instrument for FDI, we nd that inows of FDI into Mexican states are associated with a leveling of incomes at the state level+ These results provide new insights and possible directions for future research+ The existing studies on the link between globalization and income inequality have focused on the impact of trade and investment on country-level measures of income inequality+ We argue that these studies suffer from serious econometric problems+ Other studies have discussed rising income inequality across regions+ For example, scholars studying China lament the increasing income inequality within that country, partially attributed to dynamic income growth in the eastern provinces and the lagging performance of the western and central provinces+ Yet, these studies are limited in their ability to answer the question of how globalization inuences these patterns of income inequality+ In this project we nd that inows of FDI into a state lead to a leveling of income inequality within the state+ This is not to say that Mexico is becoming a more egalitarian society; many scholars have stressed that the peso crisis led to a further increase in Mexicos already high levels of income inequality+ More importantly, diminished withinstate inequality produced by FDI may actually increase national levels of inequality+ This could occur if states that attract FDI not only become more equal, but also more prosperous, as is likely to be the case+ The spread of the national distribution of income could become even wider as Mexican states converge on two different clubs: one comprising mostly poor and still extremely unequal states, the other one including more prosperous and more egalitarian states+ In fact, in the 2006 presidential election, sixteen states in the prosperous north overwhelmingly favored a candidate that espoused adherence to markets and promised further internationalization of the Mexican economy, whereas sixteen states in the poorer south supported a candidate that underscored redistribution and protection from the vagaries of the marketplace+ National-level studies have often linked globalization to increasing income inequality by suggesting that openness increases demand ~and returns! to highskilled labor relative to low-skilled labor+ We nd this mechanism to be an unlikely candidate for explaining broad changes in the level of income inequality+ This explanation is implausible in our study of Mexico because we nd that when a MNC invests in a state, the income distribution becomes atter within that state+ We speculate that this effect occurs through a localized increased demand for labor relative to that of capital+ Globalization could have complex effects on the distribution of income within a country, yet we nd that ows of FDI can also be associated with a reduction of income inequality for less-developed countries+

References
Abounoori, Esmaiel, and Patrick McCloughan+ 2003+ A Simple Way to Calculate the Gini Coefcient for Grouped as Well as Ungrouped Data+ Applied Economics Letters 10 ~8!:5059+

Foreign Investment and Income Inequality in Mexico

485

Aitken, Brian, Ann Harrison, and Robert E+ Lipsey+ 1996+ Wages and Foreign Ownership: A Comparative Study of Mexico, Venezuela, and the United States+ Journal of International Economics 40:34571+ Alderson, Arthur S+, and Franois Nielsen+ 1999+ Income Inequality, Development, and Dependence: A Reconsideration+ American Sociological Review 64 ~4!:60631+ Alesina, Alberto, and Roberto Perotti+ 1996+ Income Distribution, Political Instability, and Investment+ European Economic Review 40 ~6!:120328+ Aliber, Robert Z+ 1971+ The Multinational Enterprise in a Multiple Currency World+ In The Multinational Enterprise, edited by John H+ Dunning, 4957+ London: Allen and Unwin+ Aroca Gonzalez, Patricio, and William F+ Maloney+ 2005+ Migration, Trade, and Foreign Direct Investment in Mexico+ Policy Research Working Paper Series 3601+ Washington, D+C+: World Bank+ Baum, Christopher F+, Mark E+ Schaffer, and Steven Stillman+ 2003+ Instrumental Variables and GMM: Estimation and Testing+ Boston College Working Paper in Economics 545+ Boston: Boston College+ Beramendi, Pablo, and Thomas R+ Cusack+ 2004+ Diverse Disparities: the Politics and Economics of Wage, Market and Disposable Income Inequalities+ Working Paper SP II 2004-08+ Berlin, Germany: Social Science Research Center+ Biglaiser, Glen, and Karl DeRouen+ 2006+ Economic Reforms and Inows of Foreign Direct Investment in Latin America+ Latin American Research Review 41 ~1!:5175+ Boix, Carles+ 1998+ Political Parties, Growth and Equality: Conservative and Social Democratic Economic Strategies in the World Economy+ Cambridge: Cambridge University Press+ Bradley, David, Evelyne Huber, Stephanie Moller, Franois Nielsen, and John D+ Stephens+ 2003+ Distribution and Redistribution in Postindustrial Democracies+ World Politics 55 ~2!:193228+ Caves, Richard E+ 1971+ International Corporations: The Industrial Economics of Foreign Investment+ Economica 38 ~1!:127+ Corts, Fernando+ 2003+ El Ingreso y la Desigualdad en su Distribucin+ Mxico: 19972000+ Papeles de la Poblacin 35:13752+ Corts, Fernando, and Rosa Mara Rubalcava+ 1995+ El Ingreso de los Hogares+ Aguascalientes, Mexico: INEGI0El Colegio de Mxico0Instituto de Investigaciones Sociales-UNAM+ Dunning, John H+, ed+ 1971+ The Multinational Enterprise+ London: Allen and Unwin+ + 1977+ Trade, Location of Economic Activity and the MNE: A Search for an Eclectic Approach+ In The International Allocation of Economic Activity: Proceedings of a Nobel Symposium held at Stockholm, edited by Bertil Ohlin, Per-Ove Hesselborn, and Per Magnus Wijkman, 395 418+ London: Macmillan+ + 1981+ International Production and the Multinational Enterprise+ London: Allen and Unwin+ Esping-Andersen, Gsta+ 1990+ The Three Worlds of Welfare Capitalism+ Cambridge: Polity Press+ Feenstra, Robert C+, and Gordon H+ Hanson+ 1997+ Foreign Direct Investment and Relative Wages: Evidence from Mexicos Maquiladoras+ Journal of International Economics 42 ~3 4!:37193+ Firebaugh, Glenn+ 1999+ Empirics of World Income Inequality+ American Journal of Sociology 104 ~6!:1597 630+ Freeman, Richard B+ 1995+ Are Your Wages Set in Beijing? Journal of Economic Perspectives 9 ~3!:1532+ Garrett, Geoffrey+ 1998+ Partisan Politics in the Global Economy+ Cambridge: Cambridge University Press+ Hanson, Gordon+ 2004+ What Has Happened to Wages in Mexico Since NAFTA? In Integrating the Americas: FTAA and Beyond, edited by Toni Estevadeordal, Dani Rodrik, Alan Taylor, and Andrs Velasco, 50538+ Cambridge, Mass+: Harvard University Press+ + 2005a+ Globalization, Labor Income, and Poverty in Mexico+ NBER Working Paper Series 11027+ Cambridge, Mass+: National Bureau of Economic Research+ + 2005b+ Emigration, Labor Supply, and Earnings in Mexico+ NBER Working Paper Series 11412+ Cambridge, Mass+: National Bureau of Economic Research+

486

International Organization

Hymer, Stephan H+ 1976+ The International Operations of National Firms: A Study of Direct Foreign Investment+ Cambridge, Mass+: MIT Press+ Iversen, Torben, and Thomas R+ Cusack+ 2000+ The Causes of Welfare State Expansion: Deindustralization or Globalization? World Politics 52 ~3!:313 49+ Iversen, Torben, and David Soskice+ 2001+ An Asset Theory of Social Policy Preferences+ American Political Science Review 95 ~4!:87593+ Jensen, Nathan+ 2003+ Democratic Governance and Multinational Corporations: Political Rgimes and Inows of Foreign Direct Investment+ International Organization 57 ~3!:587 616+ + 2006+ Nation-States and the Multinational Corporation: A Political Economy of Foreign Direct Investment+ Princeton, N+J+: Princeton University Press+ Kenworthy, Lane, and Jonas Pontusson+ 2005+ Rising Inequality and the Politics of Redistribution in Afuent Countries+ Perspectives on Politics 3 ~3!:44971+ Kindleberger, Charles P+ 1969+ American Business Abroad: Six Lectures on Direct Investment+ New Haven, Conn+: Yale University Press+ Klein, Michael, Carl Aaron, and Bita Hadjimichael+ 2001+ Foreign Direct Investment and Poverty Reduction+ Policy Research Working Paper Series 2613+ Washington, D+C+: World Bank+ Korzeniewicz, Roberto P+, and William C+ Smith+ 2000+ Poverty, Inequality, and Growth in Latin America: Searching for the High Road to Globalization+ Latin American Research Review 35 ~3!:754+ Lpez-Acevedo, Gladys, Mnica Tinajero, and Marcela Rubio+ 2005+ Mexico: Human Capital Effects on Wages and Productivity+ Policy Research Working Paper Series 3791+ Washington, D+C+: World Bank+ Markusen, James R+ 1995+ The Boundaries of Multinational Enterprises and the Theory of International Trade+ Journal of Economic Perspectives 9 ~2!:16989+ Milanovic, Branko+ 1994+ The Gini-Type Functions: An Alternative Derivation+ Bulletin of Economic Research 46 ~1!:8190+ + 2005+ Worlds Apart: Measuring International and Global Inequality+ Princeton, N+J+: Princeton University Press+ Moene, Karl Ove, and Michael Wallerstein+ 2001+ Inequality, Social Insurance, and Redistribution+ American Political Science Review 95 ~4!:85974+ Moran, Theodore H+ 1998+ Foreign Direct Investment and Development: The New Policy Agenda for Developing Countries and Economies-in-transition+ Washington, D+C+: Institute for International Economics+ + 2002+ Beyond Sweatshops: Foreign Direct Investment and Globalization in Developing Countries+ Washington, D+C+: Brookings Institution Press+ Oatley, Thomas+ 1999+ How Constraining is Capital Mobility? The Partisan Hypothesis in an Open Economy+ American Journal of Political Science 43 ~4!:100327+ Pontusson, Jonas, David Rueda, and Christopher R+ Way+ 2002+ Comparative Political Economy of Wage Distribution: The Role of Partisanship and Labor Market Institutions+ British Journal of Political Science 32 ~2!:281308+ Reuveny, Rafael, and Quan Li+ 2003+ Economic Openness, Democracy, and Income Inequality: An Empirical Analysis+ Comparative Political Studies 36 ~5!:575 601+ Rodrik, Dani+ 1997+ Has Globalization Gone Too Far? Washington, D+C+: Institute for International Economics+ Rosas, Guillermo+ 2006+ Voting on Inequality? A Preliminary Test in a New Democracy+ Unpublished manuscript, Washington University, St+ Louis, Mo+ Sala-i-Martin, Xavier+ 2002+ The Disturbing Rise of Global Income Inequality+ NBER Working Paper Series 8904+ Cambridge, Mass+: National Bureau of Economic Research+ Stark, Oded, and J+ Edward Taylor+ 1991+ Migration Incentives, Migration Types: The Role of Relative Deprivation+ The Economic Journal 101 ~408!:116378+ Stolper, Wolfgang F+, and Paul A+ Samuelson+ 1941+ Protection and Real Wages+ Review of Economic Studies 9 ~1!:5873+

Foreign Investment and Income Inequality in Mexico

487

Swank, Duane+ 2002+ Global Capital, Political Institutions, and Policy Change in Developed Welfare States+ Cambridge: Cambridge University Press+ Te Velde, Dirk Willem+ 2003+ Foreign Direct Investment and Income Inequality in Latin America: Experiences and Policy Implications+ Working Paper+ London: Overseas Development Institute+ Tuman, John P+, and Craig F+ Emmert+ 2004+ The Political Economy of U+S+ Foreign Direct Investment in Latin America: A Reappraisal+ Latin American Research Review 39 ~3!:928+ Wade, Robert Hunter+ 2001+ Is Globalization Making World Income Distribution More Equal? Working Paper Series 1-10+ London: LSE Development Studies Institute+ Wallerstein, Michael+ 1999+ Wage-Setting Institutions and Pay Inequality in Advanced Industrialized Societies+ American Journal of Political Science 43 ~3!:64980+ Wood, Adrian+ 1994+ North-South Trade, Employment, and Inequality: Changing Fortunes in a SkillDriven World+ New York: Oxford University Press+ World Bank+ 2006+ World Development Report 2006: Equity and Development+ Washington, D+C+: World Bank+

You might also like