You are on page 1of 24

No.

598 August 7, 2007


�������

Don’t Increase Federal Gasoline Taxes—


Abolish Them
by Jerry Taylor and Peter Van Doren

Executive Summary

Many experts believe that gasoline taxes should State and federal gasoline taxes should be abol-
be increased for a variety of reasons. Their argu- ished. Local governments should tax gasoline only
ments are unpersuasive. Oil is not disappearing, to the extent necessary to pay for roads when user
and when it becomes more expensive, market charges are not feasible. If government feels com-
agents will substitute away from gasoline to save pelled to more aggressively regulate vehicle tailpipe
money. The link between oil price shocks and emissions or access to public roadways, pollution
recessions, although real in the 1970s, has been taxes and road user fees are better means of doing
much more benign since 1985 because of the ter- so than fuel taxes. Regardless, perfectly internaliz-
mination of price controls. Market actors proper- ing motor vehicle externalities would likely make
ly account for energy costs in their purchasing the economy less efficient—not more—by inducing
decisions absent government intervention. motorists into even more (economically) ineffi-
Pollution taxes, congestion fees, and automobile cient mass transit use.
insurance premiums more closely related to vehi- The arguments advanced against increasing
cle miles traveled are better remedies for the exter- gasoline taxes are applicable to the broader dis-
nalities associated with automobile travel than a cussion about America’s reliance on oil generally.
simple fuel tax. Gasoline consumption does not The case for policies designed to discourage oil
necessarily distort American foreign policy, consumption is nearly as threadbare as the case
impose military commitments, or empower for increasing the gasoline tax—and for largely
Islamic terrorist organizations. the same reasons.

_____________________________________________________________________________________________________
Jerry Taylor and Peter Van Doren are senior fellows at the Cato Institute. Peter Van Doren is editor of Regulation
magazine and author of Politics, Markets, and Congressional Policy Choices (University of Michigan Press,
1991). They are contributing authors to Energy and American Society—Thirteen Myths (Springer, 2007).
Fuel taxes are at ments for fuel taxes are unpersuasive because
best matters of Introduction they are second-, third-, or fourth-best reme-
dies to problems—such as automobile
local governmental Economists almost uniformly believe that tailpipe emissions and roadway congestion—
concern and markets should be left alone by government that are best remedied by direct charges on
unless market failures exist. They go on to offending externalities.
should only be a caution that government intervention will In fact, we find no compelling reason for a
fraction of improve efficiency if—and only if—the federal gasoline tax at all and call for its
current charges prospective intervention remedies one or repeal. Nor do we find any compelling case
more of those market failures. And even if for state gasoline taxes. The only circum-
on motorists. market failures exist, actual government poli- stance in which gasoline taxes might make
cies may not improve market operations, sense are those in which the transaction costs
because politicians rather than economists associated with road use charges are so high
design the policies.1 that gasoline taxes are the only reasonable
The economic case for a gasoline tax is rel- way to pay for road construction and mainte-
atively straightforward. Gasoline consump- nance. This implies that fuel taxes are at best
tion imposes costs on third parties. If gasoline matters of local governmental concern and
consumers had to compensate third parties that they should only be a fraction of current
for those costs, the total cost of gasoline charges on motorists.
would rise, demand would fall, injured parties This paper is primarily concerned with
would be made whole, and gasoline con- gasoline taxes, but the arguments we make
sumption would be optimal. But because against the gasoline tax are applicable to the
those who suffer damages find that the trans- broader policy discussion about oil’s place in
action costs associated with securing com- American society. Although liberals and con-
pensation are high, gasoline consumers do servatives, Democrats and Republicans,
not pay for the burden they impose on others. appear to agree that government should “do
Many economists believe that gasoline something” to move the country away from
taxes are too low relative to the external costs oil consumption, the case for governmental
fuel consumption imposes on others and that intervention is little different from—and no
the economy would be more efficient with a better than—the case for raising gasoline taxes.
substantial increase in the federal fuels tax.
That argument is embraced by conservatives as
well as liberals. For example, Harvard professor Energy Depletion and
Greg Mankiw, a prominent free-market econo- Future Generations
mist and former chairman of President George
W. Bush’s Council of Economic Advisers, has Because fossil fuels are exhaustible, some
recently formed “The Pigou Club,” which is gasoline tax advocates argue that we need to
made up of prominent economists and public ration production in order to save resources
intellectuals who support an increase in the for future generations.3 Future generations
federal gasoline tax.2 have no say in energy markets, but their pref-
We examine those arguments and find erences regarding resource availability in the
them unpersuasive. Some arguments for fuel future should be considered. Markets will
taxes—such as the need for society to facilitate not provide that consideration, so govern-
the inevitable transition away from an oil- ment must do so.
based economy, encourage energy conserva- Another version of this argument does
tion, or reduce foreign oil imports—fail to not emphasize the rights of future genera-
convince because they are unlikely to improve tions. Instead, it paints a picture of inevitable
upon resource allocations that would occur future shortages as production declines
absent government intervention. Other argu- occur. Fuel shortages will be accompanied by

2
price hikes, recessions, and political struggle. time and high prices some of the time are a
Those unpleasant effects can be avoided only problem, is there a market solution? Indeed
if government starts planning now. As a there is. Long-term oil futures contracts are
recent report for the U.S. Department of available to those who are worried about
Energy put it, “Intervention by governments future price increases.
will be required, because the economic and The fact that marketers have not tried to
social implications of oil peaking would be offer long-term stable prices to consumers by
otherwise chaotic.”4 arbitraging between the futures and retail
Oil depletion concerns, however, rest on markets suggests that most consumers
shaky ground. First, they are primarily about believe that they benefit by accepting low
the future availability of conventional crude spot prices most of the time in return for
oil. Unconventional crude oil deposits—such unpleasantly high spot prices some of the
as those found in heavy bitumen, tar sands, time. Said differently, we are “dependent” on
and shale rock—are extremely plentiful and oil exported from unstable countries rather
only lightly tapped at the moment because of than domestic oil or alternative sources of
high extraction costs.5 Moreover, the tech- energy, and we don’t attempt to contract our
nology exists to convert coal and natural gas way out of that instability, because it is
to synthetic petroleum liquids, which means cheaper in present value terms to remain
Markets are more
that other, more plentiful, fossil fuels could “dependent.” capable than
be harnessed to produce vast amounts of The “solution” to oil price instability is to government of
petroleum if the economics are favorable. accept higher prices most of the time in
Second, concerns that conventional crude oil return for lower prices some of the time. reacting quickly
is becoming scarce in any meaningful sense There is nothing wrong with such a trade-off and efficiently to
have not withstood close scrutiny.6 as long as it is achieved through contract.
If petroleum depletion were to become a Thirty-year fixed rate mortgages, for exam-
declines in
genuine problem, would intergenerational ple, allow consumers to shift to others the petroleum
equity demand conservation? We think not. risk of varying daily spot rates for borrowing production.
The strongest normative argument against (whose mean is lower but accompanied by
conservation is that it transfers resources higher variance) in return for higher mean
from the relatively poor to the relatively rich.7 and no variance (fixed) prices.
That’s because today’s generation is almost We don’t, however, see those sorts of con-
certainly much poorer than future genera- tracts in energy markets. Instead, what we see
tions will be. For instance, if per capita are proposals for European-style taxes on
income grows at 2 percent a year, people 100 gasoline consumption, mandated or subsi-
years from now will be approximately 7 times dized alternative energy production, and reg-
wealthier than we are today. Those concerned ulations that require energy producers to
about intergenerational equity should worry retain excess production capacity.
more about standards of living today than Unlike contractual solutions, governmen-
about standards of living tomorrow. tal solutions have the dubious distinction of
The strongest positive argument against being more expensive not just most of the
government intervention is that markets are time, but all of the time. That is, the “alterna-
more capable than government of reacting tives” to fossil fuels are more expensive than
quickly and efficiently to declines in petrole- conventional fossil fuels, even when the latter
um production. True declines, rather than prices are at peak, which is, of course, why
temporary shocks, will permanently increase such “alternatives” are not embraced without
oil prices, which will induce investments in government subsidy or coercion. For exam-
alternative energy sources and conservation. ple, we have recently calculated that the fed-
But what about temporary (albeit multi- erally owned Strategic Petroleum Reserve has
year) price shocks? If low prices most of the cost the taxpayer between $65 and $80 per

3
barrel (2004 dollars) to fill, which rivals the distant future into account because of dis-
highest spot market prices ever recorded.8 counting, but the government’s treatment of
We believe that market actors are also current versus future Social Security costs
more likely to work in the interests of future and benefits does not support the view that
generations than are governmental actors. governments are good stewards of the future.
That’s because democratically elected gov-
ernments, and the regulatory agencies estab-
lished by them, have a tendency to reflect the Oil Shocks Cause
interests of swing voters in swing voting dis- Recessions and Inflation
tricts. Accordingly, it’s unreasonable to
expect governments to be more interested in Energy supply and demand are relatively
the well-being of future generations than inflexible in the short run. As a consequence,
swing voters in swing districts who have small changes in either have very large effects
short time horizons and political prefer- on prices.10 This is the underlying reality that
ences. A single glance at America’s lavish explains why oil and gasoline prices are so
commitments to retirees in the form of volatile.11 Over a longer time period, however,
Medicare, Medicaid, and Social Security both supply and demand are more respon-
should disabuse everyone of the notion that sive to prices.12
current voters make major sacrifices for The short-run inflexibility of producers or
future generations—even when the case for consumers, and the oil price shocks that
sacrifice is mathematically indisputable. result from such inflexibility, are allegedly
The opposite, in fact, is the case; voters are responsible for inflation and recessions. The
happy to rob future generations. Economist macroeconomic damage inflicted by oil price
Jagadeesh Gokhale, for instance, calculates volatility is an external cost imposed on soci-
that the current Social Security benefit struc- ety by gasoline consumers. Analysts at the
ture taxes future generations for the benefit of Oak Ridge National Laboratory peg the mar-
those currently alive. Taxes for future genera- ginal external costs associated with oil price
tions are more than $1 trillion greater than the shocks at somewhere between 0 and $8.30
benefits they are scheduled to receive.9 per barrel of oil, or up to about 20 cents per
Markets, on the other hand, can reflect gallon of gasoline.13
longer time horizons. In fact, because the Economists disagree about the macroeco-
market value of assets is determined by nomic impact of oil shocks. Federal Reserve
expectations about what others might pay Board chairman Ben Bernanke and his col-
for them in the future, speculators represent leagues, for example, have argued that different
future generations’ interests in today’s mar- (“better”) monetary policy would reduce the
kets more effectively than politicians who recessionary effect of oil shocks, while econo-
follow swing voters—whose time horizon mists James Hamilton and Anna Herrera are
Recent work in rarely exceeds the next election. skeptical of that proposition.14 The current oil
the field tends to To summarize, there is no market failure price explosion that began in 2003 has caused
confirm the associated with oil depletion. If oil becomes far less economic harm than conventional wis-
more scarce over time, prices will rise to dom predicted, which adds credence to those
suspicion that reflect that scarcity and resources will be allo- economists who have argued that the reces-
past analyses cated efficiently. Nor is there a market failure sions that followed previous oil shocks were
associated with the interests of future gener- not caused by energy price increases.15
overstated the ations. Market agents have more incentive to Recent work in the field tends to confirm
macroeconomic consider the interests of the future than gov- the suspicion that past analyses overstated
damage caused by ernment actors because asset values are the macroeconomic damage caused by oil
affected by estimates of future profitability. price shocks. A rigorous econometric analysis
oil price shocks. We recognize that markets do not take the by economists at the Federal Reserve Bank of

4
Atlanta, for instance, suggests that oil shocks and wage rigidities that impede market Empirical
had significant effects on the macroeconomy adjustment. investigations
before 1985 but not after. They argue that the
federal price control regime of the 1970s is find that
the explanation.16 Similarly, David Walton, an Consumer Failure to consumers act far
economist at the Bank of England, argues Conserve more rationally
that wage rigidities in the 1970s were the cul-
prit.17 Economists at the Federal Reserve Claims that consumers fail to invest as than many
Bank of Cleveland, on the other hand, argue much as they should in energy efficiency are an analysts believe.
that oil price increases might be painful for often-invoked rationale for energy taxes in gen-
many, but they never have and never will eral and gasoline taxes in particular.
cause inflation. They calculate that a dou- Explanations vary as to why consumers act
bling of oil prices would lead to a one-time irrationally, but common complaints include
increase in commodity prices of about 3 per- lack of information regarding prospective sav-
cent.18 A common theme of these recent ings, cultural hostility to energy conservation,
papers is that policy-imposed rigidities in the excessively optimistic expectations about
economy were responsible for the bad eco- future energy prices, imperfect access to capi-
nomic outcomes associated with past oil price tal, and the demand for irrationally high rates
shocks, and the more flexible economy we of return.21 Appropriate energy taxes would
now have allows us to cope more easily. encourage optimal conservation expenditures.
Even though severely negative macroeco- How irrational are consumers when they
nomic consequences may not follow oil make energy decisions? Empirical investiga-
shocks, the lack of supply and demand tions find that consumers act far more ratio-
response in the short run leads to large trans- nally than many analysts believe. Clemson
fers of wealth from consumers to firms in economist Molly Espey, for example, closely
times of high prices (1979–85, 2004–07) and examined sales data from 2001 model auto-
firms to consumers in times of low prices mobiles and found that consumers actually
(1991–99). While energy policy discussions over-valued the gains possible from buying
often invoke macroeconomic or market fail- fuel-efficient vehicles.22 An earlier examina-
ure rationales for government action, the tion by Mark Dreyfus and W. Kip Viscusi
most likely source of constituent demands found that consumers discounted the sav-
for intervention in energy markets is the dis- ings from fuel efficiency by 11–17 percent
tributional concerns of firms and con- when buying automobiles, rates equivalent
sumers. Both consumers and firms attempt to returns demanded by investors from other
to enlist the assistance of government to pre- investments at the time.23
vent those wealth transfers. Thus economists undermine the argu-
Energy market interventions, however, ment that consumers are unwilling to pay
have failed to help consumers and done more for a car to reduce gasoline use during
much to damage efficiency.19 The oil price- the operating life of the vehicle. The govern-
control system in the 1970s induced short- ment has no basis for regulating the use of
ages and increased reliance on imports at a gasoline by vehicles either through a tax or
time when America’s stated policy was to through Corporate Average Fuel Economy
reduce import dependency. Consumers were Standards (CAFE) standards.24
made worse off as a consequence.20
In summary, price volatility is not a mar-
ket failure. Recent evidence suggests that Environmental Externalities
major macroeconomic damage is not caused
by oil price shocks per se but instead by poli- Gasoline tax advocates frequently argue
cy-induced rigidities including price controls that energy use causes environmental and

5
human health damages and that those costs and this increase in driving will greatly reduce the
are not reflected in energy prices. Economists emissions reductions that we might otherwise see
describe such costs as “externalities” because in response to the tax.31 Economist J. Daniel
they impose costs on others that are external Khazoom, for instance, calculates that doubling
to the prices that govern the transaction the gasoline tax under the current regulatory
between buyer and seller. Economists’ reme- regime would only reduce tailpipe emissions by 6
dy for externalities is a tax that would quan- percent over the long run.32
tify the cost of the externalities associated The third problem with a federal gasoline
with each energy source in dollar terms. The tax designed to internalize environmental
tax would force consumers to pay the exter- externalities is that the environmental and
nal cost of their energy use (which would health-related damages imposed by air emis-
“internalize the externality”).25 sions vary by location. Air sheds have variable
The underlying objective of energy taxes carrying capacities and the harms caused by
in this regard is to approximate the market emissions are largely determined by back-
that would arise if polluters had to compen- ground ambient concentration and the mar-
sate those harmed by pollution.26 An energy ginal impact of additional loads. Accordingly,
tax that considers environmental impacts a given amount of hydrocarbon tailpipe emis-
If we want to tax from energy consumption is thus an attempt sions will have a greater negative impact in
pollution, we to mimic the market that would arise if third Los Angeles, California, than in Sioux City,
should tax the parties could hold polluters liable for the Iowa. Uniform national environmental exter-
damages caused by their pollution. nality taxes will be inefficient and wrong all
emission of The first problem with a gasoline tax as a the time—too low in some areas and too high
pollutants, not means of internalizing environmental exter- in others.
nalities, however, is that it taxes the wrong The fourth problem with environmental
the raw thing. If we want to tax pollution, we should externality taxes is the difficulty associated
consumption of tax the emission of pollutants, not the raw con- with monetarizing the aggregated national
gasoline. sumption of gasoline.27 The two are not identi- health and environmental externalities asso-
cal given the differences in automobile age and ciated with energy consumption in the
maintenance. For example, 5 percent of the United States.33 Parry and his colleagues
vehicles on the road today generate 53 percent report that the plausible estimates for con-
of volatile organic compound (VOC) emis- ventional pollutants range from $.36 to
sions, while 10 percent of the vehicles on the $4.20 per gallon.34 Of course, auto emissions
road today generate 76 percent of the same.28 continue to decline from the 2000-era esti-
Given that VOC emissions are a major contrib- mates used in those calculations,35 and stud-
utor to urban smog—and that vehicles that ies that rely on toxicological risk assessments
emit unusually high loads of VOCs are likewise and epidemiological studies to ascertain
more likely to emit unusually high loads of damages may overstate human health
other pollutants—this illustrates the difficulty impacts.36 Estimates regarding the climate-
of regulating fuel consumption rather than related costs associated with consuming a
emissions. A uniform gasoline tax will overtax ton of carbon likewise vary greatly; according
some drivers and undertax others. to one survey of the literature, from $9 to
The second problem is that an increase in $200 per ton of carbon in 2000 dollars.37
gasoline taxes would have very little effect on Experts also disagree about the dollar val-
aggregate tailpipe emissions. That’s because con- ues one should attach to human morbidity,
sumers will primarily respond to a fuel tax over mortality, and environmental harms. For
the long run by purchasing more fuel efficient example, the peer-reviewed literature suggests
vehicles, not by driving less.29 And for every incre- that employers have to pay employees any-
mental increase of automotive fuel efficiency, a 20 where between $0.7 million and $16.3 million
percent increase in vehicle miles traveled follows,30 to compensate for a statistical risk of death.38

6
What number should analysts use when mon- increased probability of accidents. Those costs
etarizing mortality in externality internaliza- are not trivial. Parry and Small, for example,
tion exercises? One might try to dodge that calculate congestion externalities at 29 cents
problem by estimating the number of quality per gallon (8 cents more than the environmen-
adjusted life years (QALYs) lost through pollu- tal externalities associated with motor vehicle
tion and then calculate what it would cost gov- use)41 and accident externalities at 24 cents per
ernment to provide for an equivalent number gallon (3 cents more than the environmental
of QALYs through improved health services.39 externalities associated with motor vehicle
But that would require politicians to dedicate use). A recent paper by economists Aaron Edlin
pollution taxes to health services programs. and Pinar Karaca-Mandic estimates that acci-
Hence, pollution taxes might prove quite inef- dent externalities in California alone exceed
ficient, reflecting not the cost of pollution per $66 billion, more than current individual and
se but the cost of socialized health care. corporate income taxes collected in the state.42
A more recent estimate is offered by econ- But internalizing those externalities via a
omists Ian Parry and Kenneth Small. Their gasoline tax is a very poor way of addressing
review of the “best guesses” in the literature those problems. Better approaches include
suggests that a national gasoline tax would tolls that vary with congestion43 and the pro-
internalize environmental externalities by motion of “Pay-As-You-Drive” insurance
imposing a tax of 16 cents per gallon to pay under which premiums would vary in direct
for cost of conventional pollution and 5 proportion to vehicle miles traveled and the
cents per gallon to pay for the costs of green- insured’s risk factor as determined by insur-
house gas emissions.40 ance companies.44 Gasoline taxes are an imper-
To summarize, the environmental damages fect means to address congestion or accident
imposed on third parties by driving motor vehi- costs because such taxes don’t vary with the
cles are indeed a market failure; the costs associat- density of the setting in which driving occurs
ed with those damages are not reflected in driving or the extent to which a driver might be acci-
costs. Gasoline taxes, however, will have little dent-prone.45
effect on aggregate tailpipe emissions. The correct The futility of taxing gasoline as a second-
remedy to the problem—assuming we wish to best policy to tackle congestion is well illustrat-
address it—is an emissions charge that varies with ed by policy in London. Gasoline taxes in the
emissions as well as the capacity of the air shed to United Kingdom are $2.80 per gallon,46 more
handle extra emissions rather than a tax on gaso- than seven times higher than they are in the
line. A national emissions tax would be inefficient United States (where they average 38 cents per
because it would ignore the large geographic vari- gallon).47 Yet, high U.K. taxes have not alleviat-
ation in damages associated with pollution. And ed congestion in urban areas like London.
even though the literature provides estimates of When the municipal government in London
damages that could be used to set local emission imposed congestion-based tolls, however, to
charges, the range is so large that it provides very charge drivers for using inner-city streets, con-
little guidance to decisionmakers. gestion was greatly diminished.48 When con-
gestion charges were imposed in Stockholm in
2006, traffic likewise decreased 22 percent and
Accident and Congestion exhaust emissions decreased by 14 percent.49
Externalities Gasoline taxes
Gasoline tax advocates also see the tax as a National Security are an imperfect
means to discourage highway congestion and Externalities means to address
reduce accidents on the roadway. Drivers do
not pay the marginal costs they impose on oth- The most common rationale heard today congestion or
ers when they crowd the roads—including the for higher gasoline taxes is the complaint that accident costs.

7
From an oil consumption harms national security. tures are generally tasked with multiple mis-
economic There are four distinct arguments. First, oil sions and objectives, and oil security is simply
imports require the United States military to one mission among many. Analysts disagree
perspective, the key secure foreign production facilities and ship- about how to divide those missions into bud-
question is whether ping lanes. Second, good relations with oil pro- getary terms. Agreement about total expendi-
ducers are necessary to ensure that oil flows tures is difficult because it’s very difficult to
an elimination of into U.S. ports, but good relations with pro- know what Congress would appropriate in
U.S. military and ducers can impose unacceptably large short- various counterfactual scenarios.
foreign aid and long-term costs on the Treasury and con- Debate about the size of the U.S. military’s
tribute to anti-American sentiment, which oil mission and related foreign policy expens-
expenditures itself imposes costs. Third, oil profits fund es is not particularly relevant to gasoline
dedicated to “the Islamic extremists. Fourth, oil revenues are taxes. From an economic perspective, the key
often captured by international bad actors, and question is whether an elimination of U.S.
oil mission” would the harm done by those regimes both within military and foreign aid expenditures dedicat-
result in an and without their borders is to some extent ed to “the oil mission” would result in an
increase in the “paid for” by U.S. motorists. None of those increase in the price of oil, and, if so, how
costs, however, are paid by those who consume much? That is the true measure of the nation-
price of oil. gasoline. Hence, higher gasoline taxes would al security externality if it exists. Measuring
internalize the externalities. the externality by the amount of money gov-
In this section we examine each argument.50 ernment spends on the oil mission is at best a
measure of how much politicians believe the
Taxing for the “Oil Mission” externality might be. Political assessments
Motorists do not pay for the costs associat- may or may not be accurate.
ed with the safe and reliable delivery of foreign To be sure, if the termination of the
oil. Protecting oil tankers from harm, after all, American “oil mission” implied the termina-
is an explicit mission of the United States mili- tion of all military, police, and court services
tary. Protecting friendly oil-producing states in the region, petroleum extraction invest-
from attack is also thought by many to be an ments would become more risky, oil produc-
implicit U.S. military mission.51 tion would decrease, and prices would
Quantifying the national security costs asso- increase. But remember that oil companies in
ciated with ensuring the safe and reliable deliv- the region are creatures of government. So
ery of foreign oil is difficult. The Congressional the question is really whether Middle East
Research Service estimated in 1997 that those governments would produce less oil because
costs may be anywhere between $0.5 billion and the United States ended its oil-related mili-
$65 billion, or 1.5 cents to 30 cents per gallon tary mission and foreign aid. Or would oil
for motor fuel from the Persian Gulf.52 Deeper producing states provide—or pay others to
analysis by Mark Delucchi of the Institute of provide—military services to replace those
Transportation Studies at the University of previously provided by the United States?
California, Davis, and James Murphy at the We believe that a cessation of U.S. security
University of Massachusetts suggests that, if the assistance would be replaced by security expen-
United States did not import Persian Gulf ditures from other parties. First, oil producers
crude oil, military costs would be $11 billion— will provide for their own security needs as
$42 billion less than they are today. If we did not long as the cost of doing so results in greater
use oil at all in the motor transport sector, profits than equivalent investments could
expenditures would be $3 billion—$31 billion a yield. Because Middle Eastern governments
year less than they are today.53 typically have nothing of value to trade except
Agreement about the extent of the mili- oil, they must secure and sell oil to remain
tary’s “oil mission” is difficult to achieve viable. Second, given that their economies are
because military and foreign policy expendi- so heavily dependent on oil revenues, Middle

8
Eastern governments have even more incentive ment in producer states with unpopular
than we do to worry about the security of pro- regimes. While the costs associated with this
duction facilities, ports, and sea lanes.54 Third, distortion of foreign policy are difficult if not
even if producing countries were to provide impossible to quantify, that doesn’t make
inadequate security in the eyes of consuming them any less real. Because a higher gasoline
countries, consuming countries could pay pro- tax would reduce consumption, many believe
ducers to augment it. that high fuel taxes would give us more free-
In short, whatever security our presence pro- dom to shun odious oil-producing regimes.58
vides (and many analysts think that our presence The problem with this argument, however, is
actually reduces security)55 could be provided by that its fundamental premise is incorrect.
other parties were the United States to withdraw. Friendly relations with producer states neither
The fact that the Saudi Arabia and Kuwait paid enhance access to imported oil nor lower its price.
for 55 percent of the cost of Operation Desert Selective embargoes by producer nations on
Storm suggests that keeping the Straits of some consuming nations are unenforceable
Hormuz free of trouble is certainly within their unless (1) all other nations on Earth refuse to
means.56 The same argument applies to al Qaeda ship oil to the embargoed state, or (2) a naval
threats to oil production facilities. blockade were to prevent oil shipments into the
If oil regimes paid for their own military ports of the embargoed state. Once oil leaves the
protection and the protection of their own territory of a producer, market agents dictate Friendly relations
shipping lanes, would U.S. Middle-East mili- where the oil goes, not agents of the producer,
tary expenditures really go down? The and anyone willing to pay the prevailing world with producer
answer might well be “no” for two very dif- crude oil price can have all he wants.59 states neither
ferent reasons. First, the U.S.–Middle East The 1973 Arab oil embargo is a perfect case enhance access to
military presence stems from our implicit in point. U.S. crude oil imports actually in-
commitment to defend Israel as well as the creased from 1.7 million barrels per day (mbd) imported oil nor
region from Islamic fundamentalism, and in 1971 to 2.2 mbd in 1972, 3.2 mbd in 1973, lower its price.
those missions would not likely end simply and 3.5 mbd in 1974.60 As MIT’s Thomas Lee,
because Arab oil regimes paid for their own Ben Ball Jr., and Richard Tabors observe: “It
economic security needs. Second, bureau- was no more possible for OPEC to keep its oil
cratic and congressional inertia might leave out of U.S. supply lines than it was for the
military expenditures constant regardless of United States to keep its embargoed grain out
Israeli or petroleum defense needs.57 of Soviet silos several years later. Simple rerout-
Thus, U.S. Persian Gulf expenditures ing through the international system circum-
should not be viewed as a subsidy that lowers vented the embargo. The significance of the
oil prices below what they otherwise would embargo lay in its symbolism.”61 Granted,
be. Instead, the expenditures are a taxpayer- “there were short term supply disruptions,”
financed gift to oil regimes and the Israeli but “the only tangible effect of the embargo
government that has little, if any, effect on oil was to increase some transportation costs
prices. One may support or oppose such a slightly, because of the diversions, reroutings,
gift but not on “market failure” grounds. and transshipments necessitated.”62 MIT econ-
omist M. A. Adelman agrees:
Foreign Policy Externalities
Many foreign policy analysts think that U.S. The “embargo” of 1973–4 was a sham.
oil imports are dependent on friendly relation- Diversion was not even necessary, it
ships with oil-producing states. The fear is that was simply a swap of customers and
unfriendly regimes might not sell us oil. suppliers between Arab and non-Arab
Maintaining good relations with oil producers, sources. . . . The good news is that the
however, interferes with other foreign policy United States cannot be embargoed,
objectives and increases anti-American senti- leaving other countries undisturbed.63

9
In short, it does not matter to consumers Thus far, our analysis has examined the
to whom the oil is initially sold. All that mat- behaviors and incentive structure of incum-
ters to consumers is how much oil is pro- bent regimes. But if a radical new actor were to
duced for world markets. emerge on the global stage, how would it
Do oil-producing nations allow their feel- behave? For example, if the House of Saud
ings toward oil-consuming nations to affect were to fall and the new government consisted
their production decisions? Historically, the of Islamic extremists friendly to Osama bin
answer has been “no.” The record strongly Laden, the new regime might reduce produc-
indicates that oil-producing states, regardless tion and increase prices.67 But that scenario is
of their feelings toward the industrialized by no means certain, given that Iran—despite
West, are rational economic actors. After a all its anti-western rhetoric—has not reduced
detailed survey of the world oil market since oil output, because the Iranian economy and
the rise of OPEC, M. A. Adelman concluded, regime are dependent on oil revenue and the
“We look in vain for an example of a govern- Saudis are even more dependent.68
ment that deliberately avoids a higher income. Regardless, the departure of Saudi Arabia
The self-serving declaration of an interested from world crude oil markets would probably
party is not evidence.”64 Prof. Philip Auerswald have about the same effect on domestic oil
of George Mason University agrees, “For the prices as the departure of Iran from world
past quarter century, the oil output decisions crude oil markets in 1978. Iran accounted for
of Islamic Iran have been no more menacing or just shy of 10 percent of global oil production
unpredictable than Canada’s or Norway’s.”65 before the Iranian Revolution virtually shut
Although this is indeed the orthodox view down oil production, whereas Saudi Arabia
among oil economists, there are examples of accounts for about 13 percent of global oil
countries selling oil and natural gas to others production today.69 Oil prices increased dra-
at below-market rates: Russia sold oil to Cuba matically after the 1978 revolution, but those
at below-market prices during the Cold War; higher prices set in motion market supply-
Russia continues to sell natural gas to Ukraine and-demand responses that undermined the
at below-market prices but has ended its sub- supply reduction and collapsed world prices
sidy to Georgia as relations have soured; and eight years later. The short-term macroeco-
China sells oil to North Korea at low rates and nomic impacts of such a supply disruption
used this as leverage to induce North Korea to would actually be less today than they were
bargain over its nuclear weapons program.66 then, given the absence of price controls on
What should we learn from those cases? the U.S. economy and our reduced reliance on
First, sellers have leverage in natural gas mar- oil as an input for each unit of GDP.70
kets that is not possible in oil markets because So while it is possible that a radical oil-
oil can be transported easily while natural gas producing regime might play a game of
is shipped through pipelines. Buyers have few chicken with consuming countries, produc-
The record near-term alternatives if natural gas sellers ing countries are very dependent on oil rev-
strongly indicates reduce shipments. As liquefied natural gas enue and have fewer degrees of freedom to
gains market share, however, natural gas mar- maneuver than consuming countries.
that oil- kets will look increasingly like world crude oil Catastrophic supply disruptions would
producing states, markets and the ability of Russia or other harm producers more than consumers,
states to extract concessions from consumers which is why they are extremely unlikely.
regardless of their will dissipate. Second, the Russia–Cuba and
feelings toward China–North Korea cases involve poor coun- Oil Profits for Terrorists
the industrialized tries receiving foreign aid in the form of low- Money spent on gasoline flows to oil pro-
priced oil. We are unaware of any wealthy west- ducers, and many of those producer states use
West, are rational ern countries receiving such in-kind aid from those revenues to directly or indirectly fund
economic actors. oil-producing countries. Islamic extremists. Private individuals who

10
profit from the oil trade likewise contribute to ment, taxing gasoline to reduce revenues There is no
Islamic extremists. Those extremists pose for- flowing to Islamic terrorists might well correlation
eign policy and national security problems. increase the recruitment pool for Islamic ter-
This suggests that reduction in oil revenues rorists and make matters worse. between Persian
would reduce Islamic extremist activities. Reducing oil revenue to noxious regimes Gulf oil revenues
Before we go on, it’s worth noting that might be a risk worth taking if billions were
only 15.5 percent of the oil in the world mar- finding their way from such regimes into al
and terrorist
ket is produced from nation-states accused Qaeda coffers, but that seems unlikely. activity.
of funding terrorism.71 Hence, the vast Everything we know suggests that al Qaeda
majority of the dollars we spend on gasoline terrorist cells are “pay as you go” operations
do not end up on this purported economic that primarily engage in garden-variety crime
conveyer belt to terrorist bank accounts. to fund their activities, and Islamic charities
Regardless, terrorism is a relatively low-cost are the primary sources for organizational
endeavor, and oil revenues are unnecessary for revenue.73 Given that the governments of
terrorist activity. The fact that a few hundred Saudi Arabia, Kuwait, and others in the
thousand dollars paid for the 9/11 attacks sug- region are slated for extinction should bin
gests that the limiting factor for terrorism is Laden have his way, those governments have
expertise and manpower, not money. no interest in facilitating the transfer of oil
What is the relationship between oil prices revenues to some post office box in Pakistan.
and Islamic terrorist incidents? We estimated Producer states do indeed use oil revenues
two regressions using annual data from 1983 to fund ideological extremism, and Saudi
to 2005: the first between fatalities resulting financing of madrassas and Iranian financing of
from Islamic terrorist attacks and Saudi oil Hezbollah are good examples. But given the
prices and the second between the number of importance of those undertakings to the Saudi
Islamic terrorist incidents and Saudi oil and Iranian governments, it’s unlikely that
prices. In neither regression was the estimat- they would cease and desist simply because
ed coefficient on oil prices at all close to profits were down. They certainly weren’t
being significantly different from zero.72 deterred by meager oil profits in the 1990s.74
That probably explains why there is no The futility of reducing oil consumption as
correlation between Persian Gulf oil revenues a means of reducing terrorism is illustrated by
and terrorist activity. Inflation-adjusted oil an examination of revenues earned from oil
prices and profits during the 1990s were low. sales. A recent paper from the publishers of the
But the 1990s also witnessed the worldwide Lundberg Letter notes that oil exports from
spread of Wahhabi fundamentalism, the states accused of funding terrorism earned
build-up of Hezbollah, and al Qaeda’s com- those governments $290 billion in 2006. Even
ing of age. Note too that al Qaeda terrorists if that sum were cut by 90 percent, it would still
in the 1990s relied on help from state spon- leave $29 billion at their disposal—more than
sors such as Sudan, Afghanistan, and enough to fund terrorism given the minimal
Pakistan—nations that aren’t exactly known financial needs of terrorists. “Even a price of
for their oil wealth or robust economies. $10 per barrel crude (an unlikely scenario even
What terrorists need most is a recruiting under massive subsidy programs for plug-in
pool from which to draw. If the United States hybrid vehicles and biofuels market share man-
were to tax gasoline to such an extent that dates) would likely not cut off the purported
global oil demand, prices, and profits for oil cash flow to terror groups.”75
producers declined, the oil states would have
smaller economies and less to distribute to Rents to Bad Actors
their underemployed youth. To the extent When oil prices are high, so too are oil prof-
that deteriorating economic conditions its for infra-marginal (low-cost) producers.
breed social discontent and political resent- Even if those profits do not find their way to

11
international terrorists, they serve to prop up relatively poor country with no oil revenues to
many regimes we find distasteful. Oil produc- speak of, but it has still managed to build a
ers in the Second and Third worlds, after all, nuclear arsenal and is constantly on the
often use their robust flow of petrodollars to precipice of war with India. Impoverished, oil-
squelch human rights at home and to menace poor Egypt and Syria have at various times
neighbors abroad.76 Many analysts blame U.S. been the most aggressive anti-Israeli states in
motorists for indirectly funding these interna- the Middle East. Russia launched its war with
tional bad actors and argue that the actions of Chechnya before oil revenues engorged its trea-
these bad actors impose costs on third parties sury. While we have no doubt that (all other
that are not reflected in gasoline prices. Taxes things being a equal) a rich bad actor is more
to reduce demand would internalize this par- dangerous than a poor bad actor, the marginal
ticular externality, reduce the flow of money to impact that oil revenues have on “bad acting”
bad actors and, presumably, weaken their grip might well be rather small.
on political power. At the very least, it might Regardless, the fact that unsavory petro-
well reduce the threat they pose to others. states have been fully capable of holding on
To our knowledge, no one has attempted to to power, oppressing their people, and men-
quantify this alleged externality, and it is unlikely acing their neighbors during a decade associ-
A one-dollar hike that anyone ever will. After all, putting a price tag ated with the lowest inflation-adjusted oil
in the federal on lost civil and economic liberties, not to men- prices in history (the 1990s) suggests that
gasoline tax tion regional instability and military tension, nothing short of rendering oil nearly value-
would be extremely difficult. Moreover, one less will have any real effect on regime behav-
would reduce would need to estimate the baseline degree of ior. A one dollar hike in the federal gasoline
world crude oil “bad acting” associated with a particular regime tax, for example, would reduce world crude
or nation-state before one could estimate to what oil prices by only 1–5 percent, or by
prices by only 1–5 extent oil profits are responsible for observed $0.65–$3.25 given $65 crude—not enough to
percent—not instances of “bad acting.” Accordingly, policy- have any appreciable effect on bad acting or
enough to have makers have little concrete information at their terrorist funding. Getting prices back down
disposal to inform tax policy. to 1998 levels (the lowest inflation-adjusted
any appreciable Regardless, it is unclear to what extent oil price in history) would require a gasoline tax
effect on bad profits are associated with human rights abus- of more than $20.00 per gallon.77
acting or terrorist es or militaristic activity. There are plenty of For the sake of argument, however, let’s
examples, after all, of relatively long-lived assume that there is some incremental benefit
funding. regimes with terrible human rights records associated with reducing oil revenues to bad-
(such as North Korea) that have no oil revenues acting oil producers—an assumption that
to speak of, and this is the case even within the seems entirely reasonable. Unfortunately, we
same socioeconomic regions. Denuding Iran have only very blunt and imperfect instru-
and Libya of oil revenues might produce a gov- ments at hand to achieve that end. A gasoline
ernment that looks a lot like Syria; denuding tax, for instance, would reduce oil demand—
Venezuela of oil revenues might produce a gov- and, thus, reduce revenues—for all oil produc-
ernment that looks a lot like Cuba; and denud- ers, whether they are bad actors or not.
ing Russia of oil revenues might produce a gov- Producers in the North Sea, Canada, Mexico,
ernment that looks a lot like Russia used to be. and the United States (which collectively sup-
After all, all of these “bad-acting” petro-states plied 20.1 million barrels of oil per day in 2006,
yielded unsavory regimes even when oil rev- or 24 percent of the world’s crude oil needs
enues were a third of what they are today. that year) would be harmed just the same as
The claim that oil revenues increase the producers in Venezuela, Iran, Russia, and Libya
threat those regimes pose to their neighbors (which collectively supplied 20.3 million bar-
seems reasonable enough, but here again, it is rels per day in 2006).78
unclear to what extent this is true. Pakistan is a Imposing oil taxes to reduce profits for

12
unsavory petro-states is thus akin to taking they fear that first-best means of addressing
out a shotgun to kill a mosquito at 50 yards. externalities (direct taxes on pollution, road
You may or may not kill the mosquito, but use, etc.) are not politically feasible and that
you’re sure to hit a lot of unintended targets gasoline taxes are a second-best remedy that
when you pull the trigger. is preferable to the alternative, which is to
Given there was plenty of “bad acting” in leave externalities unaddressed.
1998, it’s unlikely that even astronomical We examine each of those arguments in
gasoline taxes would have much effect on turn.
bad acting. Accordingly, we doubt that the
foreign policy benefits that might accrue Fuel Taxes and the “Double Dividend”
from gasoline tax increases would outweigh Gasoline taxes change fuel consumption
the very real costs that such a tax would habits less than other taxes affect the con-
impose on both consumers and innocent sumption of other goods or services. They sim-
producers. We suspect that there are better ply extract revenue. From an economist’s point
remedies available to the United States to of view, that’s good. When taxes decrease con-
curtail bad behavior abroad. sumption of that which is taxed, individual
To summarize, we find little reason to welfare is reduced over and above the amount
believe that America’s national security is jeop- of the taxes actually paid. Those welfare losses
ardized to any great extent by oil consumption are thought to be quite substantial. Michigan
or that gasoline taxes could reduce whatever State economist Charles Ballard, for instance,
problems may exist. U.S. taxpayers do pay for has calculated that each additional dollar of
U.S. military activities in the Middle East, tax revenue imposes 20–30 cents of welfare loss
which are justified in part by the desire to above and beyond the losses associated direct-
secure oil production and export facilities. But ly with the tax payment.79
those expenditures are properly thought of as Hence, some observers have argued that if
wealth transfers rather than externality-creat- gasoline taxes were increased and other taxes
ing payments because their termination would decreased so that overall revenue remained
not alter oil prices. Good relations with oil pro- constant, a gasoline tax hike would provide a
ducers have no effect on the price or the avail- “double dividend.” That is, it would reduce
ability of oil in the world market. Oil revenues the negative externalities associated with
are not necessary for terrorist activity, and the gasoline consumption while also reducing
variation in terrorist activity over time does not the welfare losses associated with taxation.
seem to be related to oil revenue. And while bad Even if a gasoline tax created no net benefits,
international actors do indeed get rich off oil as long as the welfare losses associated with a
revenues, gasoline taxes are unlikely to sub- gasoline tax were smaller than the welfare
stantially reduce the degree or the extent of bad gains associated with cuts in other more dis-
acting. tortionary taxes, a gasoline tax hike would
Academic
make economic sense.80 researchers—even
But if gasoline taxes produce such bene- those who
Gasoline Taxes: fits, a tax on vehicle miles traveled would be
support
Better than the Alternative? even better because the demand for vehicle
miles traveled is even more inelastic than increasing the
Many if not most of the economists who demand for fuel.81 Given that monitoring gasoline tax—
embrace federal and state gasoline taxes con- vehicle miles traveled is quite simple and not
cede the arguments above when pressed. particularly costly, analysts who embrace the have several
They continue to support fuel taxes, howev- “double dividend” argument have no good reservations
er, for two reasons. First, they believe that fuel reason to prefer fuel taxes over taxes on vehi-
taxes are more efficient means of raising rev- cle miles traveled.
about the double-
enue than other forms of taxation. Second, However, academic researchers—even those dividend claim.

13
Although who support increasing the gasoline tax—have from the gasoline tax are used to offset cuts in
replacing capital several reservations about the double-dividend capital taxes. If the revenues are rebated to
claim.82 First, while it’s true that a gasoline tax lower-income Americans to offset the regres-
taxes with labor will not change behavior very much in gasoline sivity of the tax swap—which would almost cer-
taxes is welfare- markets, they impose significant distortions in tainly happen to some extent in the current
other markets. For instance, a gasoline tax will political climate—that would reduce the rev-
improving, the reduce after-tax wages in precisely the same enues available to “buy” cuts in capital taxes
gains associated way as a direct tax on wages. Hence, a gasoline and, thus, further reduce or eliminate the effi-
with that switch tax will introduce distortions in the labor mar- ciency gains that result from the tax swap.88
ket. It will also create distortions in other com- So while replacing capital taxes with labor
cannot be secured modity markets by reducing demand for some (consumption) taxes is welfare-improving,
absent generalized goods while increasing the demand for others. the gains associated with that switch cannot
Those distortions are at least as large as the dis- be secured absent generalized tax reform
tax reform across tortions introduced by other forms of labor across all sectors of the economy.89 As econo-
all sectors of the taxation, and they tend to “exacerbate, rather mist Stephen Smith observed after surveying
economy. than alleviate, preexisting tax distortions—even the literature:
if revenues are employed to cut preexisting dis-
tortionary taxes.”83 Ecotaxes are likely to involve distor-
But for reasons that are partially illustrated tionary costs at least as high as those
above, a gasoline tax (and a tax on virtually any involved in raising equivalent revenues
other commodity, for that matter) is implicitly through existing taxes. If the question is
a tax on labor,84 and taxing labor creates less posed whether we would choose to use
welfare loss than taxing capital.85 So even if a energy taxes, in preference for existing
gasoline tax hike leads to welfare losses in labor taxes on labour and other bases, in the
and other commodity markets, if the revenues absence of any environmental benefits,
associated with the tax were used to cut taxes then the answer is almost certainly that
on capital, it is possible that the welfare gains we would not. Energy taxes would be
associated with the capital tax reductions likely to involve just as much distortion
would exceed the welfare losses associated with of the labour market as income taxes,
increasing the gasoline tax. and at the same time distort the com-
Despite this theoretical escape hatch, the modity market. Only if there are expect-
gasoline market offers too narrow a tax base to ed to be environmental gains can the use
substitute in any substantial way for taxes on of environmental taxes be justified, and
capital. To be revenue neutral, the gasoline tax the case for ecotax reform must be made
would have to be too high. And once the tax primarily on the basis of the environ-
becomes high enough, behavior will change mental gains that would result.90
(motorists will switch from gasoline to some
other fuel—like ethanol), and behavior change
implies welfare losses. Accordingly, the efficien- First- vs. Second- vs. Third-Best Policy
cy gains that might result from a tax swap will Are gasoline taxes worth embracing as a
not offset the efficiency losses caused by the “second-best” policy, given the widespread
gasoline tax increase.86 belief that “first-best” remedies, such as direct
There are two other practical complica- taxation of the externalities in question, are off
tions. First, replacing income with gasoline the table?91 We don’t think so.
taxes decreases the efficiency of revenue collec- First, as a factual matter, it’s unclear
tion because it is cheaper to collect a given whether alleged first-best remedies such as
amount of revenue from a broad tax base rela- tailpipe emission taxes and road use charges
tive to a narrower tax base.87 Second, the “dou- are truly more difficult to pass in a legislature
ble dividend” can only occur if the revenues than fuel tax increases. Energy taxes, after all,

14
are among the most politically unpopular externality estimates, but that would pro-
taxes in America, as President Bill Clinton dis- duce correspondingly little efficiency gain
covered when he attempted to impose a Btu even in theory. As economist Stephen Smith
tax during the first year of his presidency. points out:
Pollution taxes, on the other hand, are some-
what more “virtuous” in the public’s mind, It is perhaps an over-generalization to
and highway tolls are increasingly common. If suggest that environmental taxes should
one posits that gasoline taxes are unpopular be large, or not imposed at all. However,
because they are visible, unavoidable, and the costs of complexity and the risk that
imposed on a commodity for which demand is minor environmental taxes will simply
relatively unaffected by price, then pollution be ignored should both caution against
taxes and road-use charges would likely prove too much environmental fine-tuning of
no more unpopular than gasoline taxes. the fiscal system.93
Second, economists who argue for
increased gasoline taxes rarely concede (to That’s particularly the case given that
non-economists, anyway) that those taxes are small, incremental tax increases do not guar-
deeply problematic and only worth embrac- antee only small, incremental welfare losses
ing because better policies are presumably off when the preexisting tax system is inefficient. A perfect
the table. Instead, the case for higher gasoline Relatively small carbon taxes, for example, correction of
taxes is usually offered to the public with a yield disproportionately large gross costs in gasoline
great deal of intellectual bravado that almost theoretical simulations replicating the exist-
always overstates the ability of gasoline taxes ing tax system.94 externalities
to solve identified problems.92 We believe Fourth, and most important, even if a would likely
that economists should argue for first-best gasoline tax increase were able to perfectly
policies and let the political chips fall where price gasoline’s externalities, that would not
make the economy
they may. After all, if academics (who don’t necessarily lead to greater efficiency. In fact, less, not more,
have to worry about winning popularity con- the economy might become less efficient if efficient to the
tests at the ballot box) don’t make the case gasoline prices are corrected in isolation of
for politically unpopular first-best economic other prices.95 Transportation economists, extent that even
policies, who will? Abandoning the case for including Mark Delucchi, a research scientist more inefficient
ideal policy in the public realm because it at the Institute of Transportation Studies at
may prove unpopular implicitly assumes the University of California, and Clifford
transit use
that good arguments do not persuade. It also Winston at the Brookings Institution, have increased.
requires economists to make judgments demonstrated that if all inefficiencies in
about what is politically feasible and what is transportation markets were corrected, there
not, and economists have no particular would be more, not less, automobile use than
expertise in that matter. at present because mass transit “prices” (user
Third, it’s unclear whether gasoline taxes charges) are even more distorted than the
even qualify as a “second-best” means of price of automobile travel.96 Hence, a perfect
addressing air pollution or road congestion. correction of gasoline externalities would
That’s because the difference between the likely make the economy less, not more, effi-
upper- and lower-bound externality cost esti- cient to the extent that even more inefficient
mates are larger than the marginal gains transit use increased.
promised by intervention. Hence, raising the
gasoline tax too high could well make prices
even less, not more, reflective of total costs. Conclusion
The only way to hedge against that risk is
to support gasoline tax increases that fall Many economists argue that gasoline taxes
within the lower bound of the aggregated should be increased to internalize externalities

15
associated with oil use. Some of the concerns legislative bodies have when it comes to
on which those arguments are based have no “problem-solving” exercises like this.98
(or a very weak) foundation, including con- Second, correcting motor vehicle externali-
cerns about future generations, the macroeco- ties would likely result in some incremental
nomic consequences of oil shocks, the “failure” increase in mass transit use, and that would
of consumers to conserve, and the four nation- make the economy less efficient because the
al security arguments. The concerns about the economic distortions induced by mass transit
environment, accidents, and congestion have use under the current subsidy regime are
much more validity. greater than the economic distortions induced
Regardless, it is striking that the two fre- by uninternalized motor vehicle externalities.
quently cited researchers in the literature per-
taining to motor vehicle externalities—Ian
Parry of Resources for the Future and Mark Notes
Delucchi of the Institute of Transportation 1. For a review of the literature, see The Theory of
Studies at the University of California, Davis— Market Failure: A Critical Examination, ed. Tyler
agree that internalizing those externalities via a Cowen (Fairfax, VA: George Mason University
gasoline tax should be resisted.97 The greater Press, 1988). See also Charles Wolf, Markets or
Government: Choosing Between Imperfect Alternatives
familiarity one has with the literature, the less (Cambridge, MA: MIT Press, 1991).
inclined one is to embrace gasoline taxes as a
remedy for the externalities associated with 2. A manifesto of sorts for the Pigou Club is N. Gregory
motor vehicle transport. Mankiw, “Raise the Gas Tax,” Wall Street Journal,
October 20, 2006, p. A12. A roster of inductees into the
Gasoline taxes represent a “second-best” Pigou Club is maintained on Mankiw’s website,
means of internalizing the externalities associat- http://gregmankiw.blogspot.com/2006/09/ rogoff-
ed with motor vehicle travel. Unfortu-nately, joins-pigou-club.html. Journalist Terence Corcoran
federal gasoline taxes, no matter how carefully has countered by forming the “The NoPigou Club,”
http://www.canada.com/nationalpost/features/
constructed, always send the wrong signals to nopigouclub/index.html.
motorists. When addressing road construction
and maintenance costs, for example, they over- 3. For representative arguments, see Edith Weiss,
charge motorists in low-maintenance, low-con- In Fairness to Future Generations (Dobbs Ferry, NY:
Transnational Publishers, 1989); and Paul
struction locations and undercharge those in Barresi, “Beyond Fairness to Future Generations:
high-maintenance, high-growth areas. When An Intergenerational Alternative to Intergenera-
It is striking that addressing pollution costs, they overcharge tional Equity in the International Environmental
rural motorists and undercharge many urban Arena,” Tulane Environmental Law Journal 11, no. 1
the two motorists. When addressing congestion, they (1997): 59–88.
frequently cited overcharge non-peak road users and under- 4. Robert Hirsch, Roger Bezdek, and Robert Wendling,
researchers in the charge peak road use. “Peaking of World Oil Production: Impacts, Mitiga-
In an ideal world, there would be direct exter- tion, and Risk Management,” Report Commissioned
literature nality charges rather than gasoline taxes. But by the U.S. Department of Energy, February 2005, p. 5;
http://www.hilltoplancers.org/stories/hirsch0502.pdf.
pertaining to first-best charges levied directly on pollution (via
computerized internal monitoring equipment), 5. Recoverable oil deposits within heavy bitumen in
motor vehicle congestion (via tolls), and road use (via user the Venezuelan Orinoco Belt may be nearly equal to
externalities agree Saudi proved reserves. Juan Forero, “For Venezuela,
charges) in lieu of gasoline taxes would almost A Treasure in Oil Sludge,” New York Times, June 1,
that internalizing certainly be counterproductive for two reasons. 2006, p. C1. Shale rock in the United States is esti-
First, the error bars associated with the mated to contain three times the amount of petro-
those externalities externality estimates are very large. Any leum found in proved Saudi reserves. James Bartis
et al., “Oil Shale Development in the United States:
via a gasoline tax attempt to internalize those externalities
Prospects and Policy Issues” prepared by the Rand
with government-imposed charges risks
should be reducing economic efficiency. That’s particu-
Corporation for the National Energy Technology
Laboratory of the U.S. Department of Energy, 2005.
resisted. larly the case given the poor track record that For an overview of unconventional petroleum

16
resources, see Robert L. Bradley and Richard Energy Technology,” Journal of Applied Corporate
Fulmer, Energy: The Master Resource (Dubuque, IA: Finance 16, no. 1 (Winter 2004): 48; Ian W. H. Parry
Kendall/Hunt, 2004). and Kenneth A. Small, “Does Britain or the United
States Have the Right Gasoline Tax?” Resources for
6. For a review of the literature, see Robert Arnott, the Future Discussion Paper 02-12, revised
“Supply Side Aspects of Depletion,” Journal of September 2004, p. 22; and Gilbert E. Metcalf,
Energy Literature 8, no.1 ( June 2002): 3–21. For a “Federal Tax Policy Towards Energy,” NBER
general critique regarding past and present worries Working Paper 12568, October 2006, p. 30.
about a near-term peak in global oil production, see
Vaclav Smil, Energy at the Crossroads (Cambridge, 13. Paul Leiby, et al., “Oil Imports: An Assessment
MA: MIT Press, 2003), pp. 181–213. For a withering of Benefits and Costs,” ORNL-6851, Oak Ridge
critique of current “peak oil” hypotheses, see National Laboratory, 1997.
Michael Lynch, “Crop Circles in the Dessert: The
Strange Controversy over Saudi Oil Production,” 14. Ben Bernanke, Mark Gertler, and Mark Watson,
International Research Center for Energy and “Systematic Monetary Policy and U.S. Aggregate
Economic Development, Occasional Paper 40, Economic Activity,” Brookings Papers on Economic
Boulder, Colorado, 2006; and “Crying Wolf: Peak Activity no.1 (1997): 91–142; and James Hamilton
Oil Alarmism: Fact or Fiction?” Blue Book, CLSA and Anna Maria Herrera, “Oil Shocks and
Asia-Pacific Markets, March 2007. Aggregate Macroeconomic Behavior,” Journal of
Money, Credit, and Banking 36 (April 2004): 265–86.
7. Steven Landsburg, “Tax the Knickers off Your Grand-
children,” Slate, March 7, 1997, http://www.slate.com/ 15. Donald Jones, Paul Leiby, and Inja Paik, “Oil
d/2036/. Shocks and the Macroeconomy: What Has Been
Learned Since 1996,” Energy Journal 25, no. 2
8. Jerry Taylor and Peter Van Doren, “The Case against (2004): 1–32; and Robert Barsky and Lutz Kilian,
the Strategic Petroleum Reserve,” Cato Institute Policy “Oil and the Macroeconomy since the 1970s,”
Analysis no. 555, November 21, 2005. National Bureau of Economic Research, Working
Paper 10855, October 2004.
9. Jagadeesh Gokhale, “Is the Fed Facilitating an
Unpleasant Fiscal Arithmetic?” Cato Journal 27, 16. Rajeev Dhawan and Karsten Jeske, “How
no. 2 (forthcoming): Table 2. Resilient Is the Modern Economy to Energy Price
Shocks?” Federal Reserve Bank of Atlanta Economic
10. From 2000–2006, the short run-price elasticity Review 91, no.3 ( Third Quarter, 2006): 21–32. A
for gasoline ranged from -0.034 to -0.077, that is, a new paper by U. Michigan economist Lutz Kilian
10 percent increase in gasoline prices would reduce attempts to separate oil shocks into three cate-
consumption by only about three-tenths of 1 per- gories: changes in oil supply, changes in oil
cent to about eight-tenths of 1 percent. This sug- demand resulting from changes in overall eco-
gests that consumers have become less responsive nomic activity, and changes in oil demand result-
to gasoline price increases over time, because data ing from precautionary inventory buildup (fears
from 1975–80 reveal that short-run price elasticity of future disruption). He argues that since 1975
over that time ranged from -0.21 to -0.34. Jonathan all oil price increases have been result of increases
Hughes, Christopher Knittel, and Daniel Sperling, in overall economic activity or precautionary
“Evidence of a Shift in the Short-Run Price inventory buildup. Actual reductions in crude oil
Elasticity of Gasoline Demand,” CSEM WP-159, supply have played a small role. The price increase
Center for the Study of Energy Markets, University since 2003 is the result of general economic
of California Energy Institute, September 2006. growth rather than precautionary inventory
demand. Lutz Kilian, “Not All Oil Price Shocks
11. Between March 1982 and January 2002, the stan- Are Alike: Disentangling Demand and Supply
dard deviation in monthly oil prices was 29.5 percent Shocks in the Crude Oil Market,” Social Science
of its mean. By means of comparison, the standard Research Network, February 2007, http://papers.
deviation in monthly steel prices was 9.2 percent. Oil ssrn.com/sol3/papers.cfm?abstract_id=975262.
prices fluctuate more than, or at least as much as, the
most volatile commodity prices in other sectors. 17. David Walton, “Has Oil Lost the Capacity to
Hillard Huntington, “Energy Disruptions, Interfirm Shock?” Bank of England Quarterly Bulletin 46, no. 1
Price Effects, and the Aggregate Economy,” OP 51, (Spring 2006): 105–114, http://www.bankofeng land.
September 2002, p. 4, http://www.stanford.edu/ co.uk/publications/quarterlybulletin/qb060109.pdf.
group/EMF/publications/doc/op51.pdf.
18. Eric Fisher and Kathryn Marshall, “The
12. Estimates in the literature vary from -.3 to -.9. See Anatomy of an Oil Price Shock,” Economic
Robert M. Ames, Anthony Corridore, and Paul W. Commentary, Federal Reserve Bank of Cleveland,
MacAvoy, “National Defense, Oil Imports, and Bio- November 2006.

17
19. See Joseph Kalt, The Economics and Politics of Oil Enterprise Institute, 2003), p. 23.
Price Regulation (Cambridge: MIT Press 1981); Peter
Van Doren, Politics, Markets, and Policy Choices (Ann 29. Ian Parry, “The Uneasy Case for Higher Gasoline
Arbor: University of Michigan Press, 1991); and Taxes,” Milken Institute Review 4 (2005): 43, contends
Jerry Taylor and Peter Van Doren, “Economic that 60 percent of the reduction in gasoline
Amnesia: The Case against Oil Price Controls and demand from any increase in gasoline taxes will
Windfall Profit Taxes,” Cato Institute Policy come from vehicle mileage improvements.
Analysis 561, January 12, 2006.
30. Fuel efficiency reduces the marginal costs
20. Taylor and Van Doren, “Economic Amnesia.” associated with driving, and reducing marginal
costs will induce some demand response. David
21. For representative arguments, see David Greene, Greene, James Kahn, and Robert Gibson, “Fuel
“Why CAFE Worked,” Energy Policy 26, no.8 (1998), Economy Rebound Effect for U.S. Household
pp. 595–614. Vehicles,” Energy Journal 20, no. 3 (1999): 6–10.

22. Molly Espey, “Do Consumers Value Fuel 31. Carolyn Fischer, Winston Harrington, and Ian
Economy?” Regulation 28, no. 4 (Winter 2005–06), Parry, “Economic Impacts of Tightening the
pp. 8–10. Corporate Average Fuel Efficiency Standards,” report
prepared for the U.S. Environmental Protection
23. Mark Dreyfus and W. Kip Viscusi, “Rates of Agency and the National Highway Safety
Time Preference and Consumer Valuations of Administration, 2005; J. Daniel Khazoom, “Gasoline
Automobile Safety and Fuel Efficiency,” Journal of Conservation Versus Pollution Control: Unintended
Law & Economics 38, no. 1 (April 1995): 79–105. Consequences, Continued,” Journal of Policy Analysis
and Management 7, no. 4 (1988): 710–14, and “The
24. For critiques of CAFE standards see Andrew N. Impact of a Gasoline Tax on Auto Exhaust
Kleit, “CAFE Changes, By the Numbers,” Regulation Emissions,” Journal of Policy Analysis and Management
25, no. 3 (Fall 2002): 32–35; and Paul Portney et al., 10, no.3 (1991): 434–54.
“The Economics of Fuel Economy Standards, Journal
of Economic Perspectives 17, no. 4 (Fall 2003): 214–15. 32. If EPA regulated tailpipe emissions based on
emissions per gallon rather than on emissions per
25. This argument was first made by Arthur C. mile traveled, a 9 percent increase in the gasoline tax
Pigou, The Economics of Welfare (London: Macmillan, would reduce emissions to the same extent that a
1920). doubling of the gasoline tax would have under the
current regulatory regime. Khazoom, p. 438.
26. Some economists have argued that if government
were to acknowledge and enforce private property 33. For a review of the literature, see Ian Perry and
rights over environmental resources, most environ- Kenneth Small, "Does Britain or the United States
mental regulations would be unnecessary and that Have the Right Gasoline Tax?" American Economic
the resulting legal regime would be more efficient Review 95 (September 2005): 1276–89.
than the current regulatory regime. Murray
Rothbard, “Law, Property Rights, and Air Pollution,” 34. Ian Parry, Margaret Walls, and Winston
Cato Journal 2, no 1 (Spring 1982): 55–100. But most Harrington, “Automobile Externalities and Policies,”
believe that the costs associated with policing private Resources for the Future Discussion Paper 06-26, June
environmental rights for mobile sources (“transac- 2006, p. 4, gives a range for local pollution of 1.6–18.6
tion costs” in economic parlance) would be (prohibi- cents per mile based upon an analysis from the U.S.
tively?) large. Federal Highway Administration. Assuming 22.6
miles per gallon (Parry and Small 2005, Table 1), that
27. Passenger vehicles are so heavily computerized translates into environmental costs of $.36 to $4.20
today that the technology necessary to collect emis- per gallon. The “best estimate” from the U.S. Federal
sions data for tax purposes is already onboard a Highway Administration, however, is that local envi-
large percentage of the U.S. auto fleet. If the trans- ronmental costs total 2.2 cents per mile, a figure quite
action costs associated with monitoring, collecting, close to the 2.3 cents per mile embraced by Kenneth
and billing motorists for tailpipe emissions prove Small and Camilla Kazimi, “On the Costs of Air
too large, then a fuel tax might well be a superior Pollution from Motor Vehicles,” Journal of Transport
means of internalizing the environmental external- Economics and Policy 29, (1995): 7–32. That suggests a
ities associated with automobile travel. While that plausible mean estimate of about 50 cents per gallon.
may have been true in the past, it is unlikely to be
true today. 35. Schwartz, No Way Back. Tailpipe emissions will
decline rapidly with the new Tier-2 emissions
28. Joel Schwartz, No Way Back: Why Air Pollution standards. That, combined with the improved
Will Continue to Decline (Washington: American durability of pollution control equipment, sug-

18
gests that this externality will decrease in impor- review of the literature, however, reveals that Stern’s
tance over time. estimate is at the high end of the literature. See, for
instance, William Nordhaus and Joseph Boyer,
36. For an overview of the debate and the uncertainties Warming the World: Economic Models of Global Warming
therein, see Donald McCubbin and Mark Delucci, (Cambridge, MA: MIT Press, 2000), which estimates
“The Social Cost of the Health Effects of Motor- that marginal damages associated with global warm-
Vehicle Air Pollution,” Report 11 in the series “The ing work out to about $15 per metric ton of carbon,
Annualized Social Cost of Motor Vehicle Use in the or 4 cents per gallon of gasoline.
United States, based on 1990–91 Data,” UCD-ITS-RR-
96-3(11), Institute of Transportation Studies, 41. Parry and Small 2005, p. 1283, Table 1.
University of California, Davis, August 1996, pp.
22–80, particularly pp. 22–26, http://www.its.ucdavis. 42. Aaron S. Edlin and Pinar Karaca-Mandic,
edu/publications/1996/UCD-ITS-RR-96-03(11).pdf. “The Accident Externality from Driving,” Journal
For a review of the epidemiological problems associat- of Political Economy 114, no.5 (October 2006): 951.
ed with mortality estimates from particulate matter—
the most important of the environmental externalities 43. Variable toll congestion pricing now exists in
associated with vehicle emissions—see Robert state route 91 in Orange County California, I-15 in
Crandall, Frederick Reuter, and Wilbur Steger, San Diego, I-394 in Minneapolis, and I-25 in
“Clearing the Air: EPA’s Self Assessment of Clean Air Denver. See Timothy Egan, “Paying on the Highway
Policy,” Regulation 19, no.4 (Fall 1996): 35–46; and to Get Out of First Gear,” New York Times, April 28,
Randall Lutter and Richard Belzer, “EPA Pats Itself on 2005, p. A1. For a discussion of optimal congestion
the Back,” Regulation 23, no. 3 (Fall 2000): 23–28; and pricing see Kenneth Small, Clifford Winston, and
Joel Schwartz, “Comments on EPA’s Proposed Rule, Carol Evans, Road Work (Washington: Brookings,
National Ambient Air Quality Standards for 1989); and Kenneth Small, Clifford Winston, and
Particulate Matter,” Docket ID EPA-HQ-OAR- Jia Yan, “Differentiated Road Pricing, Express
2001–0017, April 17, 2006, http://www.aei.org/ publi- Lanes, and Carpools: Exploiting Heterogenous
cations/filter.all,pubID.24240/pub_detail.asp. For a Preferences in Policy Design,” AEI-Brookings Joint
summary of other health-related air pollution contro- Center Working Paper 06-06-02, March 2006.
versies, see Joel Schwartz, “Air Pollution and Health:
Do Popular Portrayals Reflect the Scientific 44. Ian Parry, in fact, believes that such innovations
Evidence?” Environmental Policy Outlook 2 (2006). may emerge in the market with limited government
help. Parry, Walls, and Harrington, pp. 29–30.
37. R. Clarkson and K. Deyes, “Estimating the
Social Cost of Carbon Emissions,” Environmental 45. Although some economists have argued that a
Protection Economics Division, Department of tax on vehicle miles traveled (VMT) alone would
Environment, Food and Rural Affairs, London, internalize the accident externality (see, for
August 2001, cited in David Newberry, “Why Tax instance, Todd Litman, “Distance-Based Vehicle
Energy? Towards a More Rationale Policy,” The Insurance as a TDM Strategy,” Transportation
Energy Journal 26, no. 3 (2005): 21. Quarterly 51 [Summer 1997]: 119–37; and Edlin
and Karaca-Mandic, pp. 952–53), statistical analysis
38. Cass Sunstein, Risk and Reason: Safety, Law, and finds little correlation between VMT and automo-
the Environment (New York: Cambridge University bile accidents. Oddly enough, a VMT tax might
Press, 2002), Table 7.5, p. 174. have the perverse effect of actually increasing the per-
centage of bad drivers on the road because it would
39. David Newberry, “Fair Payment from Road Users: disproportionately affect good drivers. If accidents
A Review of the Evidence on Social and are more closely correlated with bad driving than
Environmental Costs,” Automobile Association, with VMT, a tax on the latter would likely increase
February 1998, cited in Newberry, “Why Tax Energy? automobile accidents. Clifford Winston and
Towards a More Rationale Policy,” The Energy Journal Vikram Maheshri, “Towards an Efficient Policy for
26, no. 3 (2005): 24. Reducing Automobile Accidents,” Working Paper,
April, 2007 (available from authors).
40. Parry and Small 2005, p. 1283, Table 1. A recent
study by economist Nicholas Stern suggests that an 46. Parry and Small 2005, p. 1276.
optimal climate change externalities tax would be
$85 per metric ton of carbon equivalent, which works 47. The figure is a weighted average of existing state
out to about a 16 cent per gallon tax on gasoline. taxes plus the federal fuels tax (U.S. Department of
Nicholas Stern, The Economics of Climate Change Transportation, Federal Highway Administration,
(London: Cambridge University Press, January 2007, Office of Highway Policy Information, 2005).
forthcoming), http://www.hm-treasury.gov.uk/inde
pendent_reviews/stern_review_economics_climate_ 48. As a consequence of road use charges, 60, 000
change/stern_review_report.cfm. Parry and Small’s (16 percent) fewer vehicles a day entered central

19
London, resulting in 30 percent less congestion. al Economics, 1993) and M. A. Adelman, The Genie
National Commission on Energy Policy, “Conges- out of the Bottle: World Oil Since 1970 (Cambridge, MA:
tion Charging: Solutions for the Escalating Prob- MIT Press, 1995).
lem of Vehicle Miles Traveled,” NCEP Background
Paper, http://www.energycommission.org/files/ 60. Energy Information Administration, Annual
finalReport/III.5.a%20-%20Congestion%20Charg Energy Review 2004, Table 5.3.
ing-VMT.pdf, pp. 1–2.
61. Thomas Lee, Ben Ball Jr,. and Richard Tabors,
49. Leila Abboud and Jenny Clevstrom, “Stockholm’s Energy Aftermath (Boston: Harvard Business
Syndrome,” Wall Street Journal, August 29, 2006, p. B1. School, 1990), p. 17.

50. Many economists doubt that there are significant 62. Ibid., p. 30. See also Edward Fried, “Oil Security: An
national security externalities associated with gaso- Economic Phenomenon,” in Oil and America’s Securi-
line consumption. See Douglas Bohi and Michael ty, ed. Edward Fried and Nanette Blandin (Washing-
Toman, The Economics of Energy Security (Norwell, MA: ton: Brookings Institution, 1988), pp. 56–59.
Kluwer Academic Publishers, 1996).
63. Cited in Robert L. Bradley Jr., The Mirage of Oil
51. Andrew Bacevich, “The Real World War IV,” Protection (Lanham, MD: University Press of
Wilson Quarterly 29, no. 1 (Winter 2005). America, 1989), p. 140. For similar arguments, see
Francisco Parra, Oil Politics: A Modern History of
52. Congressional Research Service, “Oil Imports: Petroleum (New York: I. B. Tauris, 2004), pp. 184–85.
An Overview and Update of Economic and Security
Effects,” CRS Report for Congress, 98-1, December 12, 64. Adelman, p. 31. Former OPEC Secretary-General
1997, Table A-1. Francisco Parra makes the same point in Parra.

53. Mark Delucchi and James Murphy, “U.S. 65. Philip Auerswald, “The Irrelevance of the Middle
Military Expenditures to Protect the Use of Persian- East,” American Interest, May/June 2007, p. 22.
Gulf Oil for Motor Vehicles,” Report 15 in the series
The Annualized Social Cost of Motor-Vehicle Use in the 66. See Steven Lee Meyers, “Russian Gas Company
United States, based on 1990–1991 Data, UCD-ITS- Plans Steep Price Increase for Georgia,” New York
RR-96-3(15) rev. 2, April 1996, rev. October 2006. Times, November 3, 2006, p. A12; and Joseph Kahn,
“China May Be Using Oil to Press North Korea,”
54. J. Robinson West, “Saudi Arabia, Iraq, and the New York Times, October 31, 2006, p. A12.
Gulf,” in Energy Security, ed. Jan Kalicki and David
Goldwyn (Washington: Woodrow Wilson Center 67. Bin Laden has said on many occasions that he
Press, 2005), pp. 197–218. thinks the Saudi monarchy keeps oil prices below
true market value in order to maintain friendly
55. Robert Jervis, “Why the Bush Doctrine Cannot relations with the West.
Be Sustained,” Political Science Quarterly 120, no.3
(Fall 2005): 35177. 68. Oil revenues are 40–50 percent of Iranian gov-
ernment revenues and 70–80 percent of Saudi gov-
56. Saudi Arabia and Kuwait paid approximately ernment revenues. See Energy Information Admin-
$33 billion (55 percent) toward the total cost of istration, “Country Analysis Briefs,” http://www.eia.
Desert Storm and Desert Shield, which was $60 doe.gov/emeu/cabs/contents.html. Iran’s oil out-
billion. The U.S. share was only $6 billion (10 per- put increased steadily from 3.7 mbd in 2003 to 4.1
cent). U.S. Department of Defense, news release mbd in 2005. Energy Information Administration,
125-M, May 5, 1992. International Petroleum Monthly, Table 4.1a

57. The claim that military costs are fixed rather 69. Data on Iranian production in 1978 and Saudi
than oil related is discussed in Portney et al. production in 2006 from the Energy Information
Administration; http://tonto.eia.doe.gov/merquery/
58. Jonathan Rauch, “A Higher Gas Tax Is the mer_data.asp?table=T11.01a and http://tonto.eia.
Answer. Who’ll Ask the Question?” National Journal, doe.gov/merquery/mer_data.asp?table=T11. 01b.
February 9, 2002.
70. In 1978 the U.S. used 15,950 BTUs per ($2000)
59. This is such an obvious point that energy econ- dollar of GDP but only 8,970 BTUs per ($2000) dol-
omists rarely bother to explore the issue in detail. lar of GDP in 2005, a reduction of 43.8 percent. And
To understand how the world crude oil market the BTUs used in 2005 came less from petroleum
works is to understand that embargoes are unen- than in 1978 (47.5 percent of 1978 energy consump-
forceable. See Philip Verleger, Adjusting to Volatile tion was petroleum versus only 40.5 percent in 2005).
Energy Prices (Washington: Institute for Internation- Energy Information Administration, Annual Energy

20
Review 2005, Tables 1.3 and 1.5, pp. 9 and 13. but because only 44 percent of the oil consumed in
the United States becomes gasoline (http://www.
71. Calculation from Lundberg Survey, “Fatally eia.doe.gov/neic/infosheets/petroleumproducts.ht
Flawed Premise: Why Anti-Oil Weapon in War on ml), the tax is equivalent to $18.50, or close to
Terror Won’t Work,” Energy Détente 27, no. 11 Parry’s original estimates of $20, so we used the 1 to
(November 30, 2006). 5 percent estimate and $65 a barrel crude. In 1998,
the price of oil was $13 per barrel in constant (2000)
72. Data on international Islamic terrorism incidents dollars. Average refiner acquisition costs in 2006
and fatalities were taken from the Memorial Institute were about $60 per barrel, or $52 in constant (2000)
for the Prevention of Terrorism, Terrorism Know- dollars. To reduce prices from $52 to $13 is a reduc-
ledge Base, an interactive website maintained by the tion of 75 percent, which would require a 30-fold
MIPT, http://www.tkb.org/. Data on that website increase relative to Parry’s calculation if the tax were
comes from the RAND Terrorism Chronology and on crude oil (30 * 2.5 percent, the middle of the 1–5
RAND-MIPT Terrorism Incident databases; the range, is 75 percent), or 60-fold on gasoline or about
Terrorism Indictment database; and DFI Inter- $28 per gallon.
national’s research on terrorist organizations.
Nominal Saudi oil prices were obtained from Energy 78. Energy Information Administration, International
Information Administration, Annual Energy Review Petroleum Monthly, May 8, 2007, http://www.eia.doe.
2005, p. 169, Table 5.19, “Landed Costs of Crude gov/emeu/ipsr/t22.xls.
Imports From Selected Countries,” and deflated
with the GDP deflator. Unit root tests suggested that 79. Charles Ballard, J. Shoven, and J. Whalley,
fatalities and Saudi oil prices had unit roots but ter- “General Equilibrium Computations of the Margin-
rorist incidents did not, so the former were first dif- al Welfare Costs of Taxes in the United States,”
ferenced before the regressions. Even after first differ- American Economic Review 75 (1985): 128–38.
encing, auto correlation existed so autoregressive
terms were added to each regression, which further 80. This is known as the “strong” double-dividend
weakened the insignificant relationships. claim. Weaker versions of the double-dividend
claim exist, but they are not relevant to the case for
73. Mark Basile, “Going to the Source: Why Al a major swap of more distortionary taxes in favor
Qaeda’s Financial Network Is Likely to Withstand of less distortionary energy taxes. For a discussion
the Current War on Terrorist Financing,” Studies of weaker double-dividend claims, see Lawrence
in Conflict and Terrorism 27 (2004): 169–85. Goulder, “Environmental Taxation and the
‘Double Dividend’: A Reader’s Guide,” National
74. Although little is known about funding trends Bureau of Economic Research Working Paper
associated with Iranian support for Hezbollah, the 4896, October 1994, pp. 4–8.
Iranian government probably spends no more than
$25–50 million on Hezbollah a year. Anthony 81. Parry and Small 2005, p. 1286.
Cordesman, “Iran’s Support for Hezbolla in
Lebanon,” Center for Strategic and International 82. Stanford economist Lawrence Goulder, for
Studies, July 15, 2006, p. 3. Even less is known about instance, has written one of the seminal papers crit-
Saudi contributions to Islamic extremism. See icizing the strong double-dividend claim despite
Alfred Prados and Christopher Blanchard, “Saudi the fact that he supports raising the gasoline tax
Arabia: Terrorist Financing Issues,” RL32499, CRS and is a member of Greg Mankiw’s “Pigou Club.”
Report for Congress, Congressional Research Weaker versions of the double-dividend claim,
Service, Updated December 8, 2004. however, are on much firmer ground. See Goulder.

75. Lundberg Survey, p. 8. 83. A. Lans Bovenberg and Ruud de Mooij,


“Environmental Levies and Distortionary Taxation,”
76. For a brief review of the academic literature on American Economic Review, September, 1994, pp.
this subject, which is somewhat mixed, see Paul 1085–1089. Bovenberg and de Mooij conclude that
Stevens, “Resource Impact: Curse or Blessing? A the double dividend argument holds only if the
Literature Survey,” The Journal of Energy Literature uncompensated wage elasticity of labor supply is
9, no. 1 (June 2003): 22–24. negative, but empirical investigations of the labor
market find that this is not the case.
77. This is a crude calculation based on Ian Parry’s
estimate that a $20 per barrel oil tax would reduce 84. Alan Auerbach and Laurence Kotlikoff,
long-term world crude oil prices by 1–5 percent. See Dynamic Fiscal Policy (Cambridge, England:
Ian Parry, “The Case for a Pay-by-the-Barrel Oil Cambridge University Press, 1987).
Tax,” Resources (Fall 2006 27). A $1 hike in the gas
tax is the equivalent of imposing a tax on crude of 85. The fact that taxing capital creates more wel-
$42 per barrel if all the oil were used for gasoline, fare loss than taxing labor explains why many

21
economists support a switch from income taxes 93. Smith, p. 69.
to consumption taxes. Dale Jorgenson and Kun-
Young Yun, Tax Policy and the Cost of Capital 94. Bovenberg and Goulder, and Ian Parry,
(Oxford: Oxford University Press, 1990). “Pollution Taxes and Revenue Recycling,” Working
Paper, Economic Research Service, U.S. Department
86. Goulder, pp. 15-16; Bovenberg and de Mooij; of Agriculture, April 1994, cited in Goulder, p. 30.
and A. Lans Bovenberg and Laurence Goulder,
“Optimal Environmental Taxation in the Presence 95. This is a well established and uncontroversial
of Other Taxes: An Applied Equilibrium Analysis,” concept known in economics as “the general theo-
Stanford University Working Paper, May, 1994. ry of the second best.” See R. G. Lipsey and Kelvin
Lancaster, “The General Theory of the Second
87. Wallace Oates and Ian Parry, “Policy Analysis Best,” Review of Economic Studies 24, no. 1 (1956):
in the Presence of Distorting Taxes,” Journal of 11–33; and O. Davis and A. Whinston, “Welfare
Policy Analysis and Management 19 (Fall 2000) Economics and the Theory of the Second Best,”
603–14. Review of Economic Studies 32 (1965): 1–14. For a
contemporary summary of the theory, see Jean-
88. Stephen Smith, “Environmental and Public Jacques Laffont, Fundamentals of Public Economics
Finance Aspects of the Taxation of Energy,” Oxford (Cambridge, MA: MIT Press, 1990), p. 167.
Review of Economic Policy 14, no. 4 (1998): 80–81.
96. Mark Delucchi, “Should We Try to Get the
89. See for instance Laurence Kotlikoff, “The Prices Right?” Access Magazine 16 (Spring 2000): 17.
Economic Impact of Replacing Federal Income Clifford Winston and Chad Shirley, Alternate Route
Taxes with a Sales Tax,” Cato Institute Policy Analysis (Washington: Brookings Institution, 1998), p. 58.
193, April 15, 1993.
97. Parry, Walls, and Harrington; and Delucchi,
90. Smith, p. 82. pp. 14–21.

91. For explicit concessions regarding the second- 98. David Mayhew, “Congress as Problem Solver,”
best nature of gasoline taxes, see Parry, “The Uneasy in Promoting the General Welfare: New Perspectives on
Case for Higher Gasoline Taxes,” pp. 36–45; Government Performance, ed. Alan Gerber and Eric
Newberry, “Why Tax Energy?” pp. 23–26, 29–31, Patashnik (Washington: Brookings Institution,
and 35; and Metcalf. 2006), pp. 219–36. Clifford Winston, Government
Failure versus Market Failure (Washington: Brookings
92. See, for instance, Mankiw, p. A12. Institution, 2006).

22
OTHER STUDIES IN THE POLICY ANALYSIS SERIES

597. Medicaid’s Soaring Cost: Time to Step on the Brakes by Jagadeesh


Gokhale (July 19, 2007)

596. Debunking Portland: The City That Doesn’t Work by Randal O’Toole
(July 9, 2007)

595. The Massachusetts Health Plan: The Good, the Bad, and the Ugly by David A.
Hyman (June 28, 2007)

594. The Myth of the Rational Voter: Why Democracies Choose Bad Policies
by Bryan Caplan (May 29, 2007)

593. Federal Aid to the States: Historical Cause of Government Growth and
Bureaucracy by Chris Edwards (May 22, 2007)

592. The Corporate Welfare State: How the Federal Government Subsidizes U.S.
Businesses by Stephen Slivinski (May 14, 2007)

591. The Perfect Firestorm: Bringing Forest Service Wildfire Costs under
Control by Randal O’Toole (April 30, 2007)

590. In Pursuit of Happiness Research: Is It Reliable? What Does It Imply for


Policy? by Will Wilkinson (April 11, 2007)

589. Energy Alarmism: The Myths That Make Americans Worry about Oil by
Eugene Gholz and Daryl G. Press (April 5, 2007)

588. Escaping the Trap: Why the United States Must Leave Iraq by Ted Galen
Carpenter (February 14, 2007)

587. Why We Fight: How Public Schools Cause Social Conflict by Neal
McCluskey (January 23, 2007)

586. Has U.S. Income Inequality Really Increased? by Alan Reynolds (January 8,
2007)

585. The Cato Education Market Index by Andrew J. Coulson with advisers
James Gwartney, Neal McCluskey, John Merrifield, David Salisbury, and
Richard Vedder (December 14, 2006)

584. Effective Counterterrorism and the Limited Role of Predictive Data


Mining by Jeff Jonas and Jim Harper (December 11, 2006)
583. The Bottom Line on Iran: The Costs and Benefits of Preventive War
versus Deterrence by Justin Logan (December 4, 2006)

582. Suicide Terrorism and Democracy: What We’ve Learned Since 9/11 by
Robert A. Pape (November 1, 2006)

581. Fiscal Policy Report Card on America’s Governors: 2006 by Stephen


Slivinski (October 24, 2006)

580. The Libertarian Vote by David Boaz and David Kirby (October 18, 2006)

579. Giving Kids the Chaff: How to Find and Keep the Teachers We Need
by Marie Gryphon (September 25, 2006)

578. Iran’s Nuclear Program: America’s Policy Options by Ted Galen Carpenter
(September 20, 2006)

577. The American Way of War: Cultural Barriers to Successful


Counterinsurgency by Jeffrey Record (September 1, 2006)

576. Is the Sky Really Falling? A Review of Recent Global Warming Scare
Stories by Patrick J. Michaels (August 23, 2006)

575. Toward Property Rights in Spectrum: The Difficult Policy Choices


Ahead by Dale Hatfield and Phil Weiser (August 17, 2006)

574. Budgeting in Neverland: Irrational Policymaking in the U.S. Congress


and What Can Be Done about It by James L. Payne (July 26, 2006)

573. Flirting with Disaster: The Inherent Problems with FEMA by Russell S.
Sobel and Peter T. Leeson (July 19, 2006)

572. Vertical Integration and the Restructuring of the U.S. Electricity


Industry by Robert J. Michaels (July 13, 2006)

571. Reappraising Nuclear Security Strategy by Rensselaer Lee (June 14, 2006)

570. The Federal Marriage Amendment: Unnecessary, Anti-Federalist, and


Anti-Democratic by Dale Carpenter (June 1, 2006)

576. Is the Sky Really Falling? A Review of Recent Global Warming Scare
Stories by Patrick J. Michaels (August 23, 2006)

561. Economic Amnesia: The Case against Oil Price Controls and Windfall
Profit Taxes by Jerry Taylor and Peter Van Doren (January 12, 2006)

555. The Case against the Strategic Petroleum Reserve by Jerry Taylor and
Peter Van Doren (November 21, 2005)

You might also like