You are on page 1of 19

Historical Materialism 20.

2 (2012) 105123

brill.nl/hima

Neo-developmentalism: Beyond Neoliberalism? Capitalist Crisis and Argentinas Development since the 1990s
Mariano Fliz
Universidad Nacional de La Plata and CIG-IdIHCS/CONICET-UNLP marianfeliz@gmail.com

Abstract Argentinas recent trajectory has provoked several discussions in the last few years. Most of them have centred on the character of the new mode of development presumed to have appeared in the wake of the crisis of neoliberal rule. This article provides an analysis of the changes and continuities in capitalist development in Argentina after the crisis of 2001. We provide extensive evidence regarding changes in the mode of development which, we propose, has shifted towards a neo-developmentalist alternative. While we argue that this strategy perpetuates capitalist domination, more importantly we stress that it also implies significant changes from the previous pattern of development. Particularly, the new mode of capitalist development creates a new set of public policies that mediate class-conflict in renewed ways. Keywords Argentina, crisis, neoliberalism, neo-developmentalism, class-struggle, public policies

1.Introduction In a recent review-article, Jefffery R. Webber discusses a new contribution to the analysis of neostructuralism1 in which neostructuralism is described as the ideological and theoretical underpinning of most of the new progressive governments that have been gaining support in several countries in Latin America, as part of the so-called pink tide. We believe that such a discussion is very relevant to understanding the nature of current sociopolitical transformations on the subcontinent, particularly in the midst of the deep crisis of dominant capitalist spaces. As part of this debate we present a contribution that attempts to shed some light on Argentinas conjuncture. We feel that the debate is particularly important in regard to the nature of changes
1.Webber 2010.
Koninklijke Brill NV, Leiden, 2012 DOI: 10.1163/1569206X-12341246

106

M. Fliz / Historical Materialism 20.2 (2012) 105123

in the process of capitalist development in Argentina and the rle of social forces in such changes. Clarifying the nature of the debate is of great relevance for all the new radical sociopolitical movements that are working towards social change in the region. This article is structured as follows. In Section 2 we briefly describe the process of the crisis of neoliberalism in Argentina and the original constitution of neo-developmentalism. In Section 3 we present the main novelties with regard to public policies, discussing neo-developmentalisms ties to structural continuities and changes. In Section 4 we discuss the way in which the contradictions of this new form of capitalist development manifest themselves. Finally, in Section 5 we present some preliminary conclusions.

2.From neoliberal crisis to a new form of capitalist development After a process of 30 years of restructuring, in early 2002 Argentina leaped forward out of neoliberalism.2 In consonance with several processes of popular resistance and economic crisis around the periphery (and especially in South America)3 Argentina abandoned its place as the International Monetary Funds most brilliant pupil to join the neo-developmentalist crowd. The offficial story of this transition is that a new political coalition had been formed and that it represented a radical break with its neoliberal past.4 The new policies in place represented again, according to the offficial record the rebirth of politics and the stabilisation of a new mode of development of serious capitalism (as against the speculative capitalism of previous decades) based on regained autonomy from financial capital and its representatives. Neoliberalism in Argentina was a process that began in the 1970s.5 The violent irruption of a military dictatorship in 1976 was its overt initiation with political repression and not-always-successful attempts at economic
2.In an attempt to present a preliminary definition of neoliberalism we may say that we understand it as a political project of the dominant classes to restructure society (the economy, politics, the state) in a way that will allow them to recover hegemony over the process of valorisation and capital-accumulation. In a way, it is a project for the restoration of capitalist class-power and the accelerated redistribution of wealth from the popular classes to a tiny lite (Webber 2010, p. 227). This was made possible through the variable combination of political repression, economic crisis, and deregulation and flexibilisation of economic activities. As such, through neoliberalism dominant fractions within capital have been able to reconfigure society in such a way so as to create the conditions for sustained capital-accumulation. 3.See Thwaites Rey 2010. 4.See MEP 2007. 5.While neoliberalism and neo-developmentalism are processes situated within the wider dynamics of the international economy, in this intervention we wish to concentrate our debate

M. Fliz / Historical Materialism 20.2 (2012) 105123

107

liberalisation.6 After the recuperation of democracy in 1983, Argentina entered the second stage of the neoliberal period. The stage spanning 19839 was a conflictive period of sociopolitical (class) clashes regarding the imposition of new neoliberal rules of production and reproduction of society.7 However, the dominant classes had to wait until the 1990s for a democratic government (with the election of the Peronist Carlos Menem in 1989) to be able to advance in their full-blown project of International Monetary Fund- and World Bankinspired structural reforms: the so-called convertibility-plan. The convertibility-plan included fixing the nominal exchange-rate to the US dollar, the privatisation of most public companies and public services (including social security), the flexibilisation of labour-market legislation, the deregulation of economic activities (in particular, regarding the participation of foreign capital in the local economy) and the unilateral liberalisation of foreign-trade and financial-capital movements, amongst other reforms. The result was a jump in imports of consumer-goods, the destruction of thousands of small and middle-sized firms, a hike in unemployment and poverty-rates, and the stagnation of wages and nationwide precarisation of labour.8 If the reforms were highly destructive in terms of social welfare, they simultaneously allowed for the accelerated concentration and centralisation of capital along with the growth of its acquisition by foreign firms and the improvement in industrial productivity (particularly in export-oriented agricultural and mining businesses) with the aid of the import of capital goods. Until the mid-1990s the advancement of neoliberal reforms was swift.9 However, political opposition and objective contradictions were also building up. In 1992 several trade-unions within the Confederacin General del Trabajo [General Confederation of Labour, CGT] parted and created a new confederation, Central de los Trabajadores de la Argentina [The Argentine Workers Central Union, CTA]; together with a sector that remained within the CGT (led by the truckers union) they began to express their concern at the social efffects of restructuration. In parallel, university-students, small-business organisations,

upon the less-known and understood local means through which such processes have developed in the setting of Argentina. 6.See, for example, Canitrot 1981. Actually, as a historical fact the process of transformations had its initial milestone in June 1975 with the so-called Rodrigazo, an economic programme through which the dominant classes during the Peronist government of those years began to pave the way to redesigning the whole process of capital-valorisation in Argentina. See Basualdo 2006. 7.See Bonnet and Glavich 1993. 8.See Lindenboim 2003. 9.See Bonnet 2006.

108

M. Fliz / Historical Materialism 20.2 (2012) 105123

public employees, retired workers and the unemployed began the political recomposition10 of the working class against neoliberal rule. While political reactions where escalating, neoliberalism in Argentina was also creating its own set of objective contradictions.11 The most visible elements of concern were a growing trade-deficit and a rising fiscal deficit and foreigndebt expenditures. Behind the scenes, increasing contradictions arising from the capitalist nature of production were placing pressure on capitals ability to reproduce on an expanded scale. First, a rising organic composition of capital entailed a growing inability of the economy to produce suffficient amounts of surplus-labour compared with capital expenditure. The organic composition of capital estimated as the ratio between the material substrate of constant capital (real capital-stock) and variable capital (number of hours worked in the economy) grew 15.8% in Argentina between 1992 and 1998, and then 12.7% between 1998 and 2001.12 Second, there was a growing disparity between falling unit labour-costs and nominal prices that manifested itself in a tendency towards deflation. These contradictions were displaced in time and space by rising terms of trade until 1997 and a growing world-economy until 1998. Eventually, however, the counteracting forces were unable to avoid adjustment: real GDP fell 7.7% between 1998 and 2000. From mid-1998 onwards, Argentinas economy entered a process of increasing diffficulties with respect to realising profits, accelerated transformation of available surplus-value into its financial form (interest-payments and capital-flight) and as political turmoil gained momentum the diminishing ability of capital in general to carry out successful exploitation.13 Between late 2001 and early 2002, political and economic contradictions combined to violently disarm neoliberal hegemony.14 The exit from the crisis seemed to have opened up a Pandoras box regarding political alternatives. Social opposition to neoliberal rule manifested itself in massive mobilisation and rejection of the political status quo.15 The interim government elected by Congress (Eduardo Duhalde, from the Peronist Party, was appointed president) set out to regain political control of the situation. In January 2002 the convertibility-plan was abandoned, the local currency devalued, a significant
10.See Cleaver 1985. 11.See Fliz 2011b, 2009 and 2007. 12.See Fliz 2011b. The original statistical information is that provided by offficial sources such as the Ministry of the Economy and Production (MEP), the Ministry of Labour, Employment and Social Security (MTESS), the Ministry of Social Development (MSD) and the National Institute of Statistics and the Census (INDEC), amongst others, and it is readily available from their respective web-sites. 13.See Bonnet 2006. 14.See Bonnet 2006; Carrera 2006. 15.See Dinerstein 2002.

M. Fliz / Historical Materialism 20.2 (2012) 105123

109

part of public debt entered into default, and a large part of dollar-denominated debts of private debtors were absorbed by the state and turned into public debt, amongst other measures. The immediate efffect of these policies was harsh: between 2001 and 2002, real wages fell by 19% on average, the income poverty-rate jumped to 53% of the population in May 2002, real consumption dropped 12.6% during the first trimester of 2002, and the price-index for foodstufffs went up by 48.6% within the first semester of 2002. This shaped the macroeconomic conditions for renewed capitalist expansion as profit-rates for big corporations hiked and net exports turned positive. However, it had also corresponded to a situation of great political instability, particularly due to the non-institutional struggles of the movements of unemployed workers [ piqueteros] and sectors of the middle-classes.16 To combat militant opposition by the piquetero-movement, in March 2002 the government implemented an ample income-support programme for unemployed heads of households: Plan Jefes y Jefas de Hogar Desocupados (PJJHD). These social and economic policies, combined with the targeted repression of social conflict, granted Duhaldes government enough political space to manage the initial steps in the transition out of neoliberalism. However, the repression of a piquetero-protest on 26 June 2002 that ended with the assassination of two activists by the police obliged the interim government to call for elections for early 2003. The Peronist Nstor Kirchner was elected and assumed offfice on 25 May 2003 with the objective of consolidating a new process of successful capitalist accumulation in Argentina. This process which we term neo-developmentalism was built on the new social hegemony (created during neoliberal rule) by concentrated capital and a renewed political composition of the working classes.17

3.New policies for a new form of the state Kirchners government inherited and perfected a new combination of policies that allowed for the expanded reproduction of capital with a partial recovery of employment-conditions for significant sectors within the labouring classes.

16.See Dinerstein 2002; Bonnet 2006; Carrera 2006. 17.We understand neo-developmentalism as more than discursive innovations that operate within the parameters of actually-existing neoliberalism, as Webber 2010, p. 227, sustains. As we will show, neo-developmentalism in Argentina is built on the structural transformations created by neoliberalism, but it implies much more than discursive innovations for it has signified very real changes in state-intervention, class-composition and the general dynamics of capitalist development. That said, neo-developmentalism maintains the main traits exhibited by neoliberalism but represents a whole new level of capitalist development and contradictions.

110

M. Fliz / Historical Materialism 20.2 (2012) 105123

At a macroeconomic level the orientation of policies can be reduced to five elements.18 First, the attempt at maintaining a high (competitive) and stable real exchange-rate; second, renegotiation of public debt so as to make it payable in an expansive macroeconomic environment; third, control of public expenditures (especially public employees wages) and incomes to maintain a fiscal surplus high enough to pay for the service of the renegotiated public debt; fourth, to contain wage-negotiations in the private sector within the limits of middle-run productivity-growth and objectives for the real exchangerate; fifth, to monetise the surplus of the foreign accounts (accumulation of international reserves) to control the real exchange-rate. The objective of a high and stable real exchange-rate was the key element in the new macroeconomic policy and it was aimed at maintaining the competitiveness of capital in general. For the most part, all other policies were subordinated to that end. This policy-goal has been proposed as the principal means of development.19 In fact, as explained by Robert Blecker, maintaining a high real exchange-rate by a combination of higher relative productivitygrowth and/or lower relative real wages can be thought of as an effficient way to ensure that oligopolistic capitals in a national space obtain higher profit-rates.20 From 2002 to 2009 the neo-developmentalist project in Argentina has been quite successful in respect of this objective: the level of the real exchange-rate has been on average 46.6% higher than during the boom-years of convertibility (19918) and 33.7% higher than during the crisis-years (1999 2001). This goal was achieved through the combination of a higher level of productivity (the rate between 2002 and 2009 was 52.7% higher than that between 1991 and 1998) and a level of real average wages that was 9.6% below that for 2001 (on average between 2002 and 2009). Both higher relative productivity and lower relative real wages have been one of the successful achievements of neoliberalism in terms of capitals goals.21 The result of this macroeconomic policy has been to keep profit-rates for big corporations at high historical levels: the ratio of profits to circulating capital averaged 16.6% in 20067 (according to the latest available figures) in contrast with 11.2% at the previous peak (1997).22 The post-crisis recomposition of conditions for valorisation of capital allowed for a process of sustained accumulation. From 2002 to 2008 real GDP
18.See Curia 2007; Frenkel and Rapetti 2004; FGV 2010. 19.See Frenkel and Rapetti 2004. 20.See Blecker 1999. 21.See Fliz 2009. 22.The source of the information on big corporations comes from the Survey of Big Business performed by the INDEC. It provides information on the 500 biggest-selling firms.

M. Fliz / Historical Materialism 20.2 (2012) 105123

111

grew at an average of 8.5% annually while fixed-capital investment jumped from a low 11.3% of GDP in 2002 to top 21.1% in early 2010. Accelerated growth in constant capital was accompanied by a significant increase in variable capital. Employment-levels grew by 3.4 million posts between 2002 and 2009; the unemployment rate fell from 19.7% (of the economically active population) in 2002 to 8.1% in early 2010. While on average lower than during the 1990s, real wages grew by 18.2% between 2002 and 2010 (32.6% for formal workers).23 The relative improvement in labour-conditions was a combined result of several elements at work. On the one hand, the previous process of labourpolitical recomposition gave birth to new forces within the old labourorganisations. During and especially after the crisis there was growing grass-roots agitation in the most important trade-unions. Basic struggles on the shop-floors for immediate economic demands were led by young activists in some cases tied to political organisations from the Left and their increasing uneasiness forced trade-union bureaucracies to make active demands for state-intervention.24 Secondly, the falling unemployment-rate and increasing potential demand for labour-power created better objective conditions for labours demands to be satisfied. In contrast to the neoliberal stage when capitals restructuration was the norm, neo-developmentalism was built on structural conditions tailor-made for allowing partial improvements in labour-employment at least within the formal sectors of the economy. In fact, collective bargaining gained momentum, as labour-struggles were oriented by the state and by corporations toward formal negotiation and away from direct action. The number of collective agreements went from an average of less than 200 a year between 1991 and 2001 to a peak of close to 950 in 2006.25 Finally, the states pressing need for political relegitimation led it to channel through institutional paths the demands of powerful Peronist private-sector unions, such as the Camioneros (the truckers union in the leadership of the CGT), or the Unin de Obreros Metalrgicos [Union of Metallurgical Workers, UOM] and
23.The use of the consumer-price index requires further explanation. In early 2007 the government intervened in the INDEC and began tampering with price-statistics (ATE-INDEC 2008). The goal was to reduce the offficial inflation-record and hopefully control the pricewage spiral, amongst other things. Since then, suspicion regarding the offficial consumer-price index has lead researchers to look for other sources of price-information (private surveys, information from provincial statistical offfices, etc.). For that reason, we have used as the real price-index from 2007 to 2010 the information provided by the private think-tank CENDA. While its index is not strictly comparable with the offficial one, we believe along with many other researchers in the country that it provides a more accurate account of actual consumerinflation. 24.See Etchemendy and Berins Collier 2007. 25.See MTESS 2006.

112

M. Fliz / Historical Materialism 20.2 (2012) 105123

the industrial workers union Sindicato de Mecnicos y Afines del Transporte Automotores [Union of Automotive Mechanics and Related Professions, SMATA]. This process was made possible mostly through the reactivation of traditional policies: a state-decreed, non-proportional rise in wages, increases in minimum wages, reductions in employee-paid labour-taxes and increases in child-support benefits, all for private-sector registered employees. Regarding informally employed workers and state-employees, proactive policy was much more restricted: in the first case, the incidence of public policies was limited, while in the case of public employees the objective of positive public savings (i.e., a primary fiscal surplus to allow for debt-payments) put a lid on improvements. The CTA whose mobilisation-base was the public sectors employees and teachers had little chance to influence the new government which was more inclined to look for political allies in the Peronist CGT. These policies were key in the neo-developmentalist rgimes search for political stability within a capitalist mode of development based on primary agro-mining and cheap-labour manufacturing exports.26 Bresser-Pereira, a prime advocate of neo-developmentalism in the region, puts it clearly when he states that, in an age of globalisation, export-led growth is the only viable strategy for developing countries and that it requires a competitive advantage based on a cheap labour-force.27 Thus even if it is true that successful accumulation was able to reduce general unemployment, the policy of a high and stable real exchange-rate which allowed this process was based on a simple but fundamental fact: the pervasiveness and persistence of the precariousness of work as a means to put a structural lid on labours demands.28 Even today (2010), with the economy at its peak with regards to production (real GDP) 42.5% higher than its previous peak of 1998 the incidence of non-registered labour is 44.7% in the private sector, while at least 13% of public employees have trash-contracts. Income-poverty, moreover, reportedly afffects more than 17.6% of the working population.29 The persistence of such situations is indicative of the rle played by precariousness as a means of keeping down labour-costs in the private sector and maintaining the public sectors fiscal surplus. Indeed, in comparison with registered workers, real wages for non-registered labourers and public employees have grown 23% and 122% less, respectively. This means that while real wages for registered workers have surpassed their 2001 level, in the case of non-registered and public employees they are still 5.4% and 28.9% below that level.
26.See Fliz and Lpez 2010a. 27.Bresser-Pereira 2010, p. 158. 28.See Rameri, Rafffo and Lozano 2008; Lindenboim 2008. 29.See Fliz and Lpez 2010b; Fliz, Lpez and Fernndez 2010.

M. Fliz / Historical Materialism 20.2 (2012) 105123

113

However, while neo-developmentalism in Argentina presents significant changes in macroeconomic and labour-policies, even more significant policyinnovations are evident in the sphere of social policy. As precariousness of labour remains rampant but organically integrated with the reproduction of capital, the political alliances in power since 2002 have had to deal with its political consequences. Piquetero-movements became one of the main obstacles to stability from the beginning of this new stage. The key factor in the ousting of neoliberalism and in the 2002 resistance, the piqueteros were still suffficiently uncontrollable as to require the dominant classes to adopt major policy-changes.30 First of all, as we have explained, in 2002 the government was forced to create a massive social programme (the PJJHD, within the Ministry of Social Development) to cover almost 2 million direct beneficiaries in mid-2003 with a minimum income-subsidy of 40 US dollars per month.31 Participation in the programme had almost no real prerequisites. Apart from having no formal job, that is, being unemployed, the programme required that the beneficiaries participate in community-work in social projects such as soup-kitchens, small-scale production of foodstufffs (for example, bread, cheese, etc.) or the building of local infrastructure (such as community-halls); in many cases, however, the beneficiaries were obliged to work for local governments and their political overlords, in a clientelistic fashion. To facilitate the performance of these counterpart-activities, the PJJHD was complemented by the Plan Manos a la Obra [Hands-to-Work Plan, PMO] that provided beneficiaries with access to minimum resources to acquire (in collective projects) small means of production or tools. The PJJHD was meant to weaken the social base of piquetero-organisations that in the 1990s and through direct action (roadblockades) had been able to gain from the state the control of several thousand income-benefits.32 While the almost universal access to the PJJHD reduced the political clout of the movements of the unemployed, it did not, however, completely neutralise them. Progressively minimum wages grew in real terms and the benefits of the PJJHD remained fixed in nominal (and fell in real) terms. Since its creation in 2002, the nominal value of the benefits of the PJJHD has remained at 150 pesos, while the legal minimum wage has gone from 200 pesos to 1,500 pesos. Thus, employment-growth even if precarious tended to divert some of the beneficiaries away from the PJJHD. By 2003 the government decided to go deeper into a new model of social policies put in place by the PMO: access to benefits subsequently required the
30.See Svampa and Pereyra 2003; Dinerstein, Contartese and Deledicque 2010. 31.See Fliz 2011a. 32.See Golbert 2004.

114

M. Fliz / Historical Materialism 20.2 (2012) 105123

active participation of those in need.33 The poor were expected to prove their merit in order to become beneficiaries. They were compelled to show their willingness to actively participate in socially worthwhile deeds, and the state would be the judge of such social value. These programmes were very much in line with the World Banks proposals for second-generation social policies. In fact, from the beginning this institution provided the government with financial assistance to implement many of these programmes. This was the case, for example, when the national government created the Plan Familias para la Inclusin Social [Family-Plan for Social Inclusion, Plan Familias] and the Programa de Capacitacin y Empleo [Programme of Employment and Training, PCE].34 Designed to gradually replace the PJJHD, the Plan Familias was oriented toward those deemed unemployable (for example, single mothers with children) while the PCE was oriented to the employable (for example, men).35 The only condition for participation in the Plan Familias was that beneficiaries send their children to school and medical controls, whereas in the case of the PCE beneficiaries needed to participate in training programmes and search for work. The monetary benefits of the Plan Familias and the PCE were respectively about 100 US dollars and 70 US dollars, so that progressively the beneficiaries of the PJJHD transferred to these new programmes or obtained formal employment. Together with falling unemployment, the individualisation of the benefits and segmentation of the beneficiaries meant a slow but persistent erosion of the social base of the piquetero-movements. However, while the creation of the programmes weakened these disruptive organisations, their influence remained important as they privileged direct action and non-institutional intervention. Taking this into account, the newly elected government proposed in 2003 to introduce a new paradigm in policies for social infrastructure.36 Modelled on the PMO, the Plan Federal de Emergencia Habitacional [Federal Plan for Housing Emergency, PFEH] or the Plan Agua + Trabajo [Programme for Water plus Work, PA+T] came into action. These lines of action (which included several sub-programmes) had the objective of attacking huge deficits in housing (in quantity and quality) and water-supply and sewage by paying the future beneficiaries to work on these programmes as cheap labour. As a model for further actions, participation in these programmes required that beneficiaries group together in formal cooperatives and in most cases also included the mediation of local governments. The battle for participation in these programmes required Piquetero and other social
33.See Dinerstein, Contartese and Deledicque 2010. 34.See Fliz 2011a. 35.See Fliz and Prez 2010. 36.See Dinerstein, Contartese and Deledicque 2010.

M. Fliz / Historical Materialism 20.2 (2012) 105123

115

movements to get involved in formal bureaucratic procedures that tended to partially contain disruptive actions. In addition, the government made active use of these programmes to favour allied social organisations, such as the Federacin de Tierra y Vivienda [Federation of Land and Housing, FTV].37 Such organisations were willing to accept resources in exchange for ceasing mobilisation and direct action as a means of negotiation, and generally lowered the tone of their critical interventions. Coupled with selective repression (diffferent to the widespread repression of social mobilisation during the 1990s) cooptation acted as an efffective means for social control. Conflictive normalisation of social struggles became the rule in neo-developmentalism.38 The successful combination of new macroeconomic policies, rehabilitation of traditional interventions in trade-unions, and novel social policies are key to understanding the particular characteristics of the new form of state constitutive of neo-developmentalism.

4.A new model comes with new contradictions The new form of development in Argentina (neo-developmentalism) appears to have been able to channel its contradictions in a productive way (for capital) and stabilise a new development-path.39 However, we will argue that it has only temporarily displaced some of the old contradictions, while creating a series of new ones. In neoliberal Argentina particularly during the 1990s one of the main contradictions appeared to be the opposition between productive and financial capital. This was evident, for example, in the privatisation of social security for the elderly with the creation of private pension-funds and the growing weight of public and private debt. Since 2002, we have witnessed a process of rolling back from such overt domination of finance without, however, making it disappear. There has been a reduction of public debt that included a cessation in payments on a significant portion for several years and a process of debt-reduction at the creditors cost.40 This, however, has only meant that the weight of public debt has gone back in 2009 to the 1998 levels of about 50% of GDP and interest-payments to 2.5% of GDP. Private foreign debt, meanwhile, remains at close to $US 45 billion. We must not forget that it was the process of exiting convertibility that transferred most of the private sectors
37.Ibid. 38.See Dinerstein, Contartese and Deledicque 2010. 39.See MEP 2007. 40.See Damill, Frenkel and Maurizio 2007.

116

M. Fliz / Historical Materialism 20.2 (2012) 105123

foreign-dollar debt to the state and turned debt-default into an unavoidable outcome. Before the debt-restructuring of 2005, public debt (mainly external, denominated in international currency) had on average reached 137% of GDP between 2002 and 2004. This amounted to almost 10% of GDP in terms of interest-payments, something clearly unsustainable in social, political and even economic terms, since it represented about half of the surplus-value available for accumulation between 2001 and 2002. Debt-restructuring only performed the needed devaluation of financial capital that would allow for the interests of capital as a whole to be realised within Argentine capitalism. In 2008 (during the presidency of Kirchners wife, Cristina Fernndez, who followed him in offfice) the government took the decision of recovering for the state the control of the pension-funds created in 1993 and also the flow of labour-taxes that had been directed towards those funds since then. While this was in itself seen as a positive even radical decision it was actually mandated by the need to increase fiscal receipts to maintain the primary fiscal surplus of the national state to pay for the remaining public debt. This decision, therefore, was mainly oriented toward satisfying the need to remain a solvent debtor. A second severe restriction of the 1990s was the reliance on foreign capital to finance an increasing deficit in the current account of the balance of payments that topped 4.8% in 1998. The economic exit of January 2002, which led to devaluation, also created the conditions for a radical reduction of the need for foreign savings. The jump in net exports was coupled with the sudden fall in consumption and debt-default, creating a gigantic surplus in the current account equal to 8.4% of GDP. The actual forces that led to the devaluation are related to the process of neoliberal restructuration and not simply to policydecisions taken in the aftermath of its crisis. As shown elsewhere,41 the real exchange-rate devaluation was forced by falling relative real unit labour-costs for most relevant capitals during the 1990s. This resulted in a growing tradesurplus for big corporations even while it seemed that the real exchange-rate was basically uncompetitive or over-appreciated for the economy as a whole.42 During the 1990s big corporations held a positive trade-balance even when the economy taken as a whole presented a significant deficit. Whilst during that decade unit-costs fell considerably for industrial enterprises, the exit from the neoliberal stage meant a further reduction that allowed all sectors (even relatively uncompetitive industrial branches) to swing into trade-surplus. Together with a hike in terms of trade in the early 2000s, the current account turned structurally positive, eliminating the need for financial flows to
41.See Fliz 2007, 2009. 42.See Frenkel 2003; Bonnet 2006.

M. Fliz / Historical Materialism 20.2 (2012) 105123

117

equilibrate the balance of payments. The current account has remained in surplus since 2002, averaging 4% of GDP up to 2009. The new competitiveness seemed to have gradually eliminated the need for permanent foreign financial aid. Argentina moved from a debt-led to an export-led growth-model. Chronic excess-demand for foreign currency has been displaced by persistent accumulation of international reserves, which rose by 360% between 2002 and 2009 when they reached $US 48 billion. Thirdly, while the situation of structural external surplus appears to have displaced the external restriction and its immanent contradictions, the new situation has created a new set of problems. On the one hand, a persistently high real exchange-rate and terms of trade have recreated the imbalanced nature of Argentinas productive base, boiling down to a traditional rentproducing primary sector coupled with a structurally uncompetitive industrial sector. The primary sector (agriculture and, more recently, mining) and basic manufactures are the main source of exports and hard currency while industrial branches not tied to the former have a structural deficit only countered by the high real exchange-rate policy.43 Even if higher competitiveness for the economy as a whole is as we have explained tied to higher relative productivity gained during the last stage of the neoliberal period, for the most backward branches in the economy competitiveness still relies on deep wagedevaluation and employment-precarisation. This dichotomy within the dominant classes creates a significant tension inside the neo-developmentalist project. In 2002 taxes on crop and fuel-exports were established to redirect a portion of rent from natural resources towards the industrial fractions and ease the fiscal position of the state. These transfers have become increasingly important, as the state has had to accommodate pressures from unions for improving wages and by social movements for greater social benefits. This points to a fourth central contradiction of neo-developmentalism. Relative productivity has stagnated and in the context of growing wages (especially amongst formal, unionised workers), unit-costs have begun to rise. This has put pressure on competitiveness, especially for the backward fractions of industrial capital.44 The resulting tensions were transferred to market-prices by price-setting capitals as an attempt to maintain profitability. While rising prices may be an adequate short-run solution for individual capitals to displace the impact of higher costs, for the capitalist class as a whole this may have a negative impact on international competitiveness as the real exchange-rate
43.See Azpiazu and Schorr 2010. 44.Ibid.

118

M. Fliz / Historical Materialism 20.2 (2012) 105123

tends to fall as inflation rises. For this reason, as wage-pressures got stronger in 20056 the government intervened to aid corporations setting wage-ceilings. Since in the early stages of neo-developmentalism (20036) higher wagedemands came hand in hand with grass-roots agitation,45 the government had to rely this time on a combination of bureaucratic control of union-membership (mainly through the CGT leadership), the Ministry of Labours intervention, and targeted repression of relevant conflicts (for example, Buenos Aires floating casino, Kraft Foods, the synthetic-fibres manufacturer Mafissa, etc.). This strategy was successful in stealing control of the political initiative away from grass-roots movements and allowed bureaucracies to channel demands within rational boundaries. However, as the presidential elections of 2007 neared and inflationary pressures increased pushed by commodity-speculation in worldmarkets wage-demands also surged. Unable to halt declining competitiveness, the government reformed statistical price-information to hide actual inflation.46 However, in the year following Cristina Fernndezs 2007 election as president as part of the same political alliance of Nestor Kirchner, in an attempt to curb increasing prices in foodstufffs the government proposed to increase the rate of export-taxes. This generated an unforeseen protest from rural producers and exporters, which included roadblocks and massive mobilisations.47 Three months later Congress rejected the export-tax hike, with the vice-president of the governing coalition and acting president of the Senate voting against his own government. In mid-2008, the world-crisis hit Argentinas economy. While the impact on trade was substantial and growth fell to almost zero, a controlled nominal devaluation of the currency along with higher unemployment helped to control wage-demands; average real wages stagnated for the next two years, putting a limit to falling competitiveness. By 2010, the economy recovered its impetus and was growing at a nine-percent annual rate. The aforementioned tensions continue to characterise a process that has nonetheless shown itself to be quite strong and politically stable.48

5.Neo-developmentalism: beyond neoliberalism? In the previous sections we have discussed the novelties, continuities and contradictions surrounding a new stage of capitalist development in Argentina:
45.See Antn, Cresto, Rebn and Salgado 2010. 46.See ATE-INDEC 2008. 47.See Grigera 2009; Sartelli, Harari, Kabat, Kornblihtt, Baudino, Dachevsky and Sanz Cerbino 2008. 48.In October 2010 Nstor Kirchner unexpectedly died. In the short-run, this is arguably the main sign of diffficulties for the continuation of the neo-developmentalist project.

M. Fliz / Historical Materialism 20.2 (2012) 105123

119

neo-developmentalism. However, in what sense, if any, can neo-developmentalism be called post-neoliberal? In what ways does it surpass the neoliberal project? To answer this question we need to acknowledge that neoliberalism was a classproject led by dominant classes around the world to impose the restructuration of capitalist relations of production and reproduction so as to overcome the conditions that led to the capitalist crisis in the 1960s and 1970s.49 In South America and particularly in Argentina first military dictatorships and, later, elected governments were the means for such transformations to come to pass.50 As such, the neoliberal project was successful in its class-goals.51 During the 1990s, in Argentina as in many other countries of South and Central America social upheavals led by old and new social movements in the context of economic contradictions led to the displacement of the neoliberal impetus for reform. In many ways this meant as we have seen for Argentina the formation of new political alliances that have been able to redirect the form of capitalist development in new directions.52 Neo-developmentalism has implied a new form of state-intervention, a diffferent composition of the working classes (that includes new forms of political intervention), and renewed conditions for capital-accumulation. In contrast with the structural adjustment of the crisis-ridden neoliberal stage, neo-developmentalism in Argentina seems to profile a new historical process of capitalist development dominated by expanded reproduction of capital in the context of peripheral transnationalisation and the structural precariousness of living conditions, but with some room for relative improvements led by new forms of labour-struggle. The main diffference between the two models is that while neoliberalism was a historical process led by the strategy of the dominant classes for structural change, neo-developmentalism is a process built on the success of such a strategy for the constitution of a renewed base for capitalist development. This diffference does not manifest itself so much in the economic structure (put in place during the neoliberal stage) but in the new forms and results of the sociopolitical intervention of class-actors in, through and beyond the state. The structural (economic and political) bases for this new form of development were put in place during the neoliberal process and particularly during the 1990s, above all through the convertibility-strategy. In this sense, neo-developmentalism was born out of the transformations brought forth by
49.See Harvey 2009. 50.See Bonnet and Glavich 1993. 51.See Webber 2010. 52.By contrast, in the developed countries the possibilities for working people to successfully confront the neoliberal project are still in doubt, as events in recent years seem to indicate.

120

M. Fliz / Historical Materialism 20.2 (2012) 105123

neoliberalism. Argentinas economy is now much more globalised than ever before. This can be seen in the internationalisation of local capital and the penetration of transnational capital in every form of capital: mercantile (international commerce grew from 16.2% of GDP in 1993 to more than 24.2% in 1998 and after the crisis of 2001 to 23.8% in 2004), financial (foreign debt went from US$ 87.5 billion in 1994 to more than US$ 147.6 billion in 1998, reaching US$ 128.2 billion in 2008 even after the debt-restructuring of 2005) and productive (foreign-owned enterprises went from representing 32% of the top 500 firms in 1993 to more than 48% in 1998 and 66% in 2007). In this framework, the state in the periphery, while limited by the heritage of the neoliberal period, has had to find new ways to create conditions for successful accumulation after the fall of the neoliberal age. The state still faces the contradiction between the generalisation of the law of value (transnationalisation being its latest form) that tends to erase national borders, and the very real exigency of gaining political legitimacy to allow for the reproduction of a particular social formation within a particular national value-space.53 The idea of a neo-developmentalist state refers to a state-form that recognises the power of the working class as a subject within capital and thus the need to orient this power to productive use (for capital).54 Neo-developmentalism is more than just a tactical response of the ruling classes to adjust to the social contradictions generated by the implementation of neoliberalism.55 In a way, it is a new process of capitalist development that includes the recomposition of the labour-classes in old and new forms of organisation. From the recognition of these changes comes the granting of several concessions to workers, concessions that are accompanied by a more direct intervention of the governmental apparatus in the regulation of economic activity and the promotion of capitalist development. However, unlike the developmentalist experience of the 1950s and 1960s (associated with so-called Fordism), the neo-developmentalist state operates in the framework set by a post-neoliberal society characterised by the predominance of a wider domination of capitalist relations and transnational capital. This limits the character of the states intervention and makes it very diffficult to reintroduce traditional developmentalism. In fact, while the state appears to have more clout in the economy than before, the boundaries for welfare-policies and for directing the general orientation of capitalist development have been strictly narrowed.56 Argentina, as we have discussed,
53.See Thwaites Rey 2010; Burnham 1997; Panitch and Gindin 2005. 54.See Cleaver 1985. 55.Webber 2010, p. 227. 56.See Thwaites Rey and Castillo 2008.

M. Fliz / Historical Materialism 20.2 (2012) 105123

121

is a prime example of this. In the Argentine case, neo-developmentalism is a work-in-progress,57 an attempt so far successful of the dominant classes to maintain their hegemonic control.

References
Antn, Gustavo, Jorge Cresto, Julin Rebn and Rodrigo Salgado 2010, Una dcada en disputa. Apuntes sobre las luchas sociales en Argentina, OSAL, 28: 95116. ATE-INDEC 2008, ndice de precios al consumidor IPC-GBA del ao 2007: ejercicio alternativo ante la imposibilidad del clculo del IPC-GBA debido a la intervencin del INDEC, Junta Interna/Comisin Tcnica ATE-INDEC, working document, 4. Azpiazu, Daniel and Martn Schorr 2010, Hecho en Argentina, Buenos Aires: Siglo XXI. Basualdo, Eduardo 2006, Estudios de historia econmica argentina. Desde mediados del siglo XX a la actualidad, Buenos Aires: FLACSO/Siglo veintiuno editores. Blecker, Robert 1999, Kaleckian Macro Models for Open Economies, in Foundations of International Economics: Post-Keynesian Perspectives, edited by Johan Deprez and John T. Harvey, London: Routledge. Bonnet, Alberto 2006, Qu se vayan todos!: Discussing the Argentine Crisis and Insurrection, Historical Materialism, 14, 1: 15784. Bonnet, Alberto and Eduardo Glavich 1993, El huevo y la serpiente: Notas acerca de la crisis del rgimen democrtico de dominacin y la reestructuracin capitalista en Argentina, 19831993 (primera parte), Cuadernos del Sur, 16: 929. Bresser-Pereira, Luiz Carlos 2010, Globalizacin y competencia. Apuntes para una macroeconoma estructuralista del desarrollo, Buenos Aires: Siglo XXI Editora Iberoamericana. Burnham, Peter 1997, Estado y mercado en la economa poltica internacional: una crtica marxiana, Doxa: Cuadernos de Ciencias Sociales, 16, 517. Canitrot, Adolfo 1981, Orden social y monetarismo, Buenos Aires: Estudios CEDES. Carrera, Juan Iigo 2006, Argentina: The Reproduction of Capital Accumulation through Political Crisis, Historical Materialism, 14, 1: 185219. Cleaver, Harry 1985, Una lectura poltica de El Capital, Mexico City: Fondo de Cultura Econmica. Curia, Eduardo 2007, Teora del modelo de desarrollo de la Argentina: las condiciones para su continuidad, Buenos Aires: Galerna. Damill, Mario, Roberto Frenkel and Roxana Maurizio 2007, Macroeconomic Policy Changes in Argentina at the Turn of the Century, Nuevos documentos CEDES, 29, 51140, available at: <http://www.ilo.org/public/english/bureau/inst/download/114e.pdf>. Dinerstein, Ana Cecilia 2002, The Battle of Buenos Aires: Crisis, Insurrection and the Reinvention of Politics in Argentina, Historical Materialism, 10, 4: 538. Dinerstein, Ana Cecilia, Daniel Contartese and Melina Deledicque 2008, Notas de investigacin sobre la innovacin organizacional en entidades de trabajadores desocupados en la Argentina, Revista Realidad Econmica, 234: 5079. 2010, La ruta de los piqueteros, Buenos Aires: Capital Intelectual. Etchemendy, Sebastin and Ruth Berins Collier 2007, Down but Not Out: Union Resurgence and Segmented Neocorporatism in Argentina: 20032007, Politics and Society, 35, 3: 363401. Fliz, Mariano 2007, A Note on Argentina, Its Crisis and the Theory of Exchange Rate Determination, Radical Review of Political Economics, 39, 1: 8099. 57.See Katz 2010.

122

M. Fliz / Historical Materialism 20.2 (2012) 105123

2009, Crisis cambiaria en Argentina, Problemas del Desarrollo. Revista Latinoamericana de Economa, 40, 158: 185213. 2011a, The Macroeconomic Limits of Incomes Policy in a Dependent Country: The Need and Possibilities for Radical Reforms in Social Policies in Argentina after the Crisis, 20012008, in Strategies Against Poverty: Designs from the North and Alternatives from the South, edited by Alicia Puyana Mutis and Samwel Ongwen Okuro, Buenos Aires: CLACSO. 2011b, Un estudio sobre la crisis en un pas perifrico. La economa argentina del crecimiento a la crisis, 19912002, Buenos Aires: Editorial El Colectivo. Fliz, Mariano and Emiliano Lpez 2010a, La dinmica del capitalismo perifrico posneoliberalneodesarrollista. Contradicciones, barreras y lmites de la nueva forma de desarrollo en Argentina, Herramienta. Revista de debate y crtica marxista, 45, available at: <http://www .memoria.fahce.unlp.edu.ar/art_revistas/pr.4654/pr.4654.pdf>. 2010b, Polticas sociales y laborales en la Argentina: del Estado ausente al Estado posneoliberal, in Pensamiento crtico, organizacin y cambio social, edited by Mariano Fliz, L. Melina Deledicque, Emiliano Lpez and Facundo Barrera, Buenos Aires: Centro de Estudios para el Cambio Social/Editorial El Colectivo. Fliz, Mariano, Emiliano Lpez and Lisandro Fernndez 2010, Estructura de clase, distribucin del ingreso y polticas pblicas. Una aproximacin al caso argentino en la etapa post-neoliberal, availableat:<http://marianfeliz.files.wordpress.com/2010/10/02-02-jec-2010-feliz-lopezfernandez.pdf>. Fliz, Mariano and Pablo E. Prez 2010, Polticas pblicas y las relaciones entre capital y trabajo. Contrastes y continuidades en la pos-convertibilidad a la luz de la historia argentina, in El movimiento obrero en disputa. La organizacin colectiva de los trabajadores, su lucha y resistencia en la Argentina del siglo XX, edited by Claudia Figari, Paula Lenguita and Juan Monts Cat, Buenos Aires: CEIL-PIETTE/CONICET-Fundacin Centro Integral Comunicacin, Cultura y Sociedad-Ediciones CICCUS. FGV 2010, Ten Theses on New Developmentalism, Structuralist Development Macroeconomics Center, School of Economics, Getulio Vargas Foundation, San Paulo. Frenkel, Roberto 2003, Deuda externa, crecimiento y sostenibilidad, Desarrollo Econmico, 42, 168: 54562. Frenkel, Roberto and Martn Rapetti 2004, Polticas macroeconmicas para el crecimiento y el empleo, paper prepared for the International Labour Organisation, Geneva. Golbert, Laura 2004, Derecho a la inclusin o paz social? Plan Jefes y Jefas de Hogar Desocupados, Serie Polticas Sociales, Volume 84, Santiago de Chile: ECLAC. Grigera, Juan 2009, Right-wing Social Movements? The Argentinean Development Model in Question, paper delivered at the Historical Materialism Sixth Annual Conference, London. Harvey, David 2009, Estamos realmente ante el fin del neoliberalismo?, Herramienta. Revista de debateycrticamarxista,41,availableat:<http://www.herramienta.com.ar/revistaherramienta-n-41/estamos-realmente-ante-el-fin-del-neoliberalismo>. Katz, Claudio 2010, Los nuevos desequilibrios de la economia argentina, Anuario EDI, 5: 513. Lindenboim, Javier 2003, El mercado de trabajo en la Argentina en la transicin secular: cada vez menos y peores empleos, in Entre el trabajo y la poltica. Las reformas de las polticas sociales argentinas en perspectiva comparada, edited by Javier Lindenboim and Claudia Danani, Buenos Aires: Editorial Biblos. 2008, Trabajo, ingresos y polticas en Argentina. Contribuciones para pensar el siglo XXI, Buenos Aires: Eudeba. MEP 2007, Lineamientos Estratgicos para el Desarrollo Productivo de la Argentina, document for discussion, Ministry of the Economy and Production, Buenos Aires. MTESS 2006, Evolucin y Estado de los Convenios Colectivos sobre Salarios, unpublished report, Subsecretara de Programacin Tcnica y Estudios Laborales, Ministerio de Trabajo, Empleo y Seguridad Social (MTESS).

M. Fliz / Historical Materialism 20.2 (2012) 105123

123

Panitch, Leo and Sam Gindin 2005, El liderazgo del capital global, New Left Review, II, 35: 4768. Rameri, Ana, Toms Rafffo and Claudio Lozano 2008, Sin mucho que festejar: radiografia actual del mercado laboral y las tendencias postconvertibilidad, paper delivered at the Instituto de Estudios y Formacin, Central de los Trabajadores Argentinos, 15 May, Buenos Aires. Sartelli, Eduardo, Fabin Harari, Marina Kabat, Juan Kornblihtt, Vernica Baudino, Fernando Dachevsky and Gonzalo Sanz Cerbino 2008, Patrones en la ruta. El conflicto agrario y los enfrentamientos en el seno de la burguesa, Buenos Aires: Ediciones ryr. Svampa, Maristela and Sebastin Pereyra 2003, Entre la ruta y el barrio. La experiencia de las organizaciones piqueteras, Buenos Aires: Editorial Biblos. Thwaites Rey, Mabel 2010, Despus de la globalizacin neoliberal: Qu Estado en Amrica Latina?,OSAL,27,availableat:<http://bibliotecavirtual.clacso.org.ar/ar/libros/secret/ cuadernos/32/32.t.rey.pdf>. Thwaites Rey, Mabel and Jos Castillo 2008, Desarrollo, dependencia y Estado en el debate latinoamericano, Revista Araucaria, 10, 19, available at: <http://institucional.us.es/araucaria/ nro19/ideas19_2.htm>. Webber, Jefffery R. 2010, Review of Latin American Neostructuralism: The Contradictions of PostNeoliberal Development, Historical Materialism, 18, 3: 20829.

You might also like