You are on page 1of 18

ECON 520 MANAGERIAL ECONOMICS ASSIGNMENT

Perfect Competition - Economics of Competitive Markets

HUDA ISA ALI AL MUTAWAJ 201220199 5th November 2013

Perfect Competition Economics of Competitive Markets

Huda Isa Al Mutawaj

201220199

Perfect Competition - Economics of Competitive Markets

Perfect competition a pure market Perfect competition is a theoretical market structure. It is primarily used as a benchmark against which other, real-life market structures are compared. The industry that most closely resembles perfect competition in real life is agriculture. Perfect competition is the opposite of a monopoly, in which only a single firm supplies a particular good or service, and that firm can charge whatever price it wants because consumers have no alternatives and it is difficult for would-be competitors to enter the marketplace. Under perfect competition, there are many buyers and sellers, and prices reflect supply and demand. Also, consumers have many substitutes if the good or service they wish to buy becomes too expensive or its quality begins to fall short. New firms can easily enter the market, generating additional competition. Companies earn just enough profit to stay in business and no more, because if they were to earn excess profits, other companies would enter the market and drive profits back down to the bare minimum. Real-world competition differs from the textbook model of perfect competition in many ways. Real companies try to make their products different from those of their competitors. They advertise to try to gain market share. They cut prices to try to take customers away from other firms. They raise prices in the hope of increasing profits. And some firms are large enough to affect market prices. But the perfect competition model is not an ideal that we should try to achieve in the real world. Perfect competition describes a market structure whose assumptions are strong and therefore unlikely to exist in most real-world markets. Economists have become more interested in pure competition partly because of the growth of e-commerce as a means of buying and selling goods and services. And also because of the popularity of auctions as a device for allocating scarce resources among competing ends.

Perfect Competition Economics of Competitive Markets

Huda Isa Al Mutawaj

201220199

Assumptions for a perfectly competitive market

Many sellers each of whom produce a low percentage of market output and cannot influence the prevailing market price.

Many individual buyers, none has any control over the market price Perfect freedom of entry and exit from the industry. Firms face no sunk costs and entry and exit from the market is feasible in the long run. This assumption means that all firms in a perfectly competitive market make normal profits in the long run.

Homogeneous products are supplied to the markets that are perfect substitutes. This leads to each firms being price takers with a perfectly elastic demand curve for their product.

Perfect knowledge consumers have all readily available information about prices and products from competing suppliers and can access this at zero cost in other words, there are few transactions costs involved in searching for the required information about prices. Likewise sellers have perfect knowledge about their competitors.

Perfectly mobile factors of production land, labour and capital can be switched in response to changing market conditions, prices and incentives.

No externalities arising from production and/or consumption.

Evaluation Understanding the real world of imperfect competition! It is often said that perfect competition is a market structure that belongs to out-dated textbooks and is not worthy of study! Clearly the assumptions of pure competition do not hold in the vast majority of real-world markets, for example, some suppliers may exert control over the amount of goods and services supplied and exploit their monopoly power. On the demand-side, some consumers may have monopsony power against their suppliers because they purchase a high percentage of total demand. Think for example about the buying power wielded by the major supermarkets when it comes to sourcing

Perfect Competition Economics of Competitive Markets

Huda Isa Al Mutawaj

201220199

food and drink from food processing businesses and farmers. The Competition Commission has recently been involved in lengthy and detailed investigations into the market power of the major supermarkets. In addition, there are nearly always some barriers to the contestability of a market and far from being homogeneous; most markets are full of heterogeneous products due to product differentiation in other words, products are made different to attract separate groups of consumers. Consumers have imperfect information and their preferences and choices can be influenced by the effects of persuasive marketing and advertising. In every industry we can find examples of asymmetric information where the seller knows more about quality of good than buyer a frequently quoted example is the market for second-hand cars! The real world is one in which negative and positive externalities from both production and consumption are numerous both of which can lead to a divergence between private and social costs and benefits. Finally there may be imperfect competition in related markets such as the market for key raw materials, labour and capital goods. Adding all of these points together, it seems that we can come close to a world of perfect competition but in practice there are nearly always barriers to pure competition. That said there are examples of markets which are highly competitive and which display many, if not all, of the requirements needed for perfect competition. In the example below we look at the global market for currencies. Currency markets - taking us closer to perfect competition

The global foreign exchange market is where all buying and selling of world currencies takes place. There is 24-hour trading, 5 days a week. Trading volume in the Forex market is around $3 trillion per day equivalent to the annual GDP of France! 31% of global trading takes place in London alone. Most trading in currencies is speculative.

Perfect Competition Economics of Competitive Markets

Huda Isa Al Mutawaj

201220199

The main players in the currency markets are as follows:

Banks both as market makers dealing in currencies and also as end -users demanding currency for their own operations.

Hedge funds and other institutions (e.g. funds invested by asset managers, pension funds).

Central Banks (including occasional currency intervention in the market when they buy and sell to manipulate an exchange rate in a particular direction).

Corporations (for example airlines and energy companies who may use the currency market for defensive hedging of exposures to risk such as volatile oi l and gas prices.)

Private investors and people remitting money earned overseas to their country of origin / market speculators trading in currencies for their own gain / tourists going on holiday and people traveling around the world on business.

Why does a currency market come close to perfect competition?

Homogenous output: The "goods" traded in the foreign exchange markets are homogenous - a US dollar is a dollar and a euro is a euro whether someone is trading it in London, New York or Tokyo.

Many buyers and sellers meet openly to determine prices: There are large numbers of buyers and sellers - each of the major banks has a foreign exchange trading floor which helps to "make the market". Indeed there are so many sellers operating around the world that the currency exchanges are open for business twenty-four hours a day. No one agent in the currency market can, on their own influence price on a persistent basis - all are price takers. According to Forex_Broker.net "The intensity and quantity of buyers and sellers ready for deals doesn't allow separate big participants to move the market in joint effort in their own interests on a long-term basis."

Currency values are determined solely by market demand and supply factors. High quality real-time information and low transactions costs: Most buyers or sellers are well informed with access to real-time market information and
5

Perfect Competition Economics of Competitive Markets

Huda Isa Al Mutawaj

201220199

background research analysis on the factors driving the prices of each individual currency. Technological progress has made more information immediately available at a fraction of the cost of just a few years ago. This is not to say that information is cheap - an annual subscription to a Bloomberg or a Reuters news terminal will cost several thousand dollars. But the market is rich with information and transactions costs for each batch of currency bought and sold has come down.

Seeking the best price: The buyers and sellers in foreign exchange only deal with those who offer the best prices. Technology allows them to find the best price quickly.

What are the limitations of currency trading as an example of a competitive market?

Firstly the market can be influenced by official intervention via buying and selling of currencies by governments or central banks operating on their behalf. There is a huge debate about the actual impact of intervention by policy-makers in the currency markets.

Secondly there are high fixed costs involved in a bank or other financial institution when establishing a new trading platform for currencies. They need the capital equipment to trade effectively; the skilled labour to employ as currency traders and researchers. Some of these costs may be counted as sunk costs hard to recover if a decision is made to leave the market.

Despite these limitations, the foreign currency markets take us reasonably close to a world of perfect competition. Much the same can be said for trading in the equities and bond markets and also the ever expanding range of future markets for financial investments and internationally traded commodities. Other examples of competitive markets can be found on a local scale for example a local farmers market where there might be a number of farmers offering their produce for sale.

Perfect Competition Economics of Competitive Markets

Huda Isa Al Mutawaj

201220199

The internet and perfect competition

Advances in web technology have made markets more competitive. It has reduced barriers to entry for firms wanting to compete with well-established businesses for example specialist toy retailers are better able to battle for market share with the dominant retailers such as ToysRUs and Wal-Mart.

One of the most important aspects of the internet is the ability of consumers to find information about prices for many goods and services. There are an enormous number of price comparison sites in the UK covering everything from digital cameras to package holidays, car insurance to CDs and jewellery.

That said the price comparison web sites themselves have come under criticism. For example the sites offering to compare hundreds of different motor insurance policies or mortgage products draw information from the insurance and mortgage brokers but might use limiting assumptions about the different types of consumers looking for the best price the result is a range of prices facing the consumer that dont accurately reflect their precise needs and consumers may only realise this when, for example, they make a claim on an insurance policy bought over the internet which turns out not to provide the specific cover they needed.

And in the market for price comparison sites there is monopoly power too! Moneysupermarket.com currently has around 40% of the overall comparison site market, with Confused.com its nearest rival with a share of about 10%.

Perfect Competition Economics of Competitive Markets

Huda Isa Al Mutawaj

201220199

Price and output in the short run under perfect competition

In the short run, the interaction between demand and supply determines the market-clearing price. A price P1 is established and output Q1 is produced. This price is taken by each firm. The average revenue curve is their individual demand curve.

Since the market price is constant for each unit sold, the AR curve also becomes the marginal revenue curve (MR) for a firm in perfect competition.

For the firm, the profit maximising output is at Q2 where MC=MR. This output generates a total revenue (P1 x Q2). Since total revenue exceeds total cost, the firm in our example is making abnormal (economic) profits.

This is not necessarily the case for all firms in the industry since it depends on the position of their short run cost curves. Some firms may be experiencing subnormal profits if average costs exceed the price and total costs will be greater than total revenue.

Perfect Competition Economics of Competitive Markets

Huda Isa Al Mutawaj

201220199

The adjustment to the long-run equilibrium in perfect competition

If most firms are making abnormal profits in the short run, this encourages the entry of new firms into the industry

This will cause an outward shift in market supply forcing down the price The increase in supply will eventually reduce the price until price = long run average cost. At this point, each firm in the industry is making normal profit.

Other things remaining the same, there is no further incentive for movement of firms in and out of the industry and a long-run equilibrium has been established. This is shown in the next diagram.

Perfect Competition Economics of Competitive Markets

Huda Isa Al Mutawaj

201220199

We are assuming in the diagram above that there has been no shift in market demand.

The effect of increased supply is to force down the price and cause an expansion along the market demand curve. But for each supplier, the price they take is now lower and it is this that drives down the level of profit made towards normal profit equilibrium.

In an exam question you may be asked to trace and analyse what might happen if

There was a change in market demand (e.g. arising from changes in the relative prices of substitute products or complements.)

There was a cost-reducing innovation affecting all firms in the market or an external shock that increases the variable costs of all producers.

10

Perfect Competition Economics of Competitive Markets

Huda Isa Al Mutawaj

201220199

Adam Smith on Competition The natural price or the price of free competition ... is the lowest which can be taken. [It] is the lowest which the sellers can commonly afford to take, and at the same time continue their business. Source: Adam Smith, the Wealth of Nations (1776), Book I, Chapter VII Characteristics of competitive markets The common characteristics of markets that are considered to be competitive are:

Lower prices because of many competing firms. The cross-price elasticity of demand for one product will be high suggesting that consumers are prepared to switch their demand to the most competitively priced products in the marketplace.

Low barriers to entry the entry of new firms provides competition and ensures prices are kept low in the long run.

Lower total profits and profit margins than in markets which dominated by a few firms. Greater entrepreneurial activity the Austrian school of economics argues that competition is a process. For competition to be improved and sustained there needs to be a genuine desire on behalf of entrepreneurs to innovate and to invent to drive markets forward and create what Joseph Schumpeter called the gales of creative destruction.

Economic efficiency competition will ensure that firms move towards productive efficiency. The threat of competition should lead to a faster rate of technological diffusion, as firms have to be responsive to the changing needs of consumers. This is known as dynamic efficiency.

11

Perfect Competition Economics of Competitive Markets

Huda Isa Al Mutawaj

201220199

The importance of non-price competition In competitive markets, non-price competition can be crucial in winning sales and protecting or enhancing market share. Perfect competition and efficiency Perfect competition can be used as a yardstick to compare with other market structures because it displays high levels of economic efficiency. 1. Allocative efficiency: In both the short and long run we find that price is equal to marginal cost (P=MC) and thus allocative efficiency is achieved. At the ruling price, consumer and producer surplus are maximised. No one can be made better off without making some other agent at least as worse off i.e. we achieve a Pareto optimum allocation of resources. 2. Productive efficiency: Productive efficiency occurs when the equilibrium output is supplied at minimum average cost. This is attained in the long run for a competitive market. Firms with high unit costs may not be able to justify remaining in the industry as the market price is driven down by the forces of competition. 3. Dynamic efficiency: We assume that a perfectly competitive market produces homogeneous products in other words, there is little scope for innovation designed purely to make products differentiated from each other and allow a supplier to develop and then exploit a competitive advantage in the market to establish some monopoly power. Some economists claim that perfect competition is not a good market structure for high levels of research and development spending and the resulting product and process innovations. Indeed it may be the case that monopolistic or oligopolistic markets are more effective long term in creating the environment for research and innovation to flourish. A cost-reducing innovation from one producer will, under the assumption of perfect information, be immediately and without cost transferred to all of the other suppliers.
12

Perfect Competition Economics of Competitive Markets

Huda Isa Al Mutawaj

201220199

That said a contestable market provides the discipline on firms to keep their costs under control, to seek to minimise wastage of scarce resources and to refrain from exploiting the consumer by setting high prices and enjoying high profit margins. In this sense, competition can stimulate improvements in both static and dynamic efficiency over time. The long run of perfect competition, therefore, exhibits optimal levels of economic efficiency. But for this to be achieved all of the conditions of perfect competition must hold including in related markets. When the assumptions are dropped, we move into a world of imperfect competition with all of the potential that exists for various forms of market failure

13

Perfect Competition Economics of Competitive Markets

Huda Isa Al Mutawaj

201220199

Profit maximization The objective of any firm, including a competitive firm, is to maximize its profits. As a result of the price-taking assumption above, the firm can sell all it wants at price "p". The firm is too smale to influence the market price. That is, the firm faces a horizontal demand curve at price "p". If it is profitable for the firm to expand output as long as the extra revenue (price or marginal revenue) from selling an additional unit exceeds the extra cost (marginal cost) of producing that unit. The profit is maximum when Marginal Cost

Price

Price Marginal cost Price Price Price > = <

vs

Marginal profit positive 0 negative

Total Profit increases maximum decreases

Marginal cost Marginal cost Marginal cost

14

Perfect Competition Economics of Competitive Markets

Huda Isa Al Mutawaj

201220199

Example : results of a competitive firm q 1'000 2'000 3'000 4'000 5'000 6'000 7'000 8'000 9'000 10'000 11'000 12'000 12'452 13'000 TC 128'000 184'000 218'000 236'000 244'000 248'000 254'000 268'000 296'000 344'000 418'000 524'000 668'000 747'120 856'000 R 60'000 120'000 180'000 240'000 300'000 360'000 420'000 480'000 540'000 600'000 660'000 720'000 747'120 780'000 Profit -128'000 -124'000 -98'000 -56'000 -4'000 52'000 106'000 152'000 184'000 196'000 182'000 136'000 52'000 0 -76'000 -152.00 212.00 Marginal Profit 16.00 35.00 48.00 55.00 56.00 51.00 40.00 23.00 -29.00 -64.00 -105.00 MC 69.00 44.00 25.00 12.00 5.00 4.00 9.00 20.00 37.00 60.00 89.00 124.00 165.00 Price 60.00 60.00 60.00 60.00 60.00 60.00 60.00 60.00 60.00 60.00 60.00 60.00 60.00 60.00 60.00

15

Perfect Competition Economics of Competitive Markets

Huda Isa Al Mutawaj

201220199

Empirical approach Empirically we observe that the competitive firm output which maximizes its profit is 9.000 at a market price of 60 (do not change) The profit of the firm is maximum when market price = Marginal Cost (MC)

MC = Variation of Total Cost when output varies of one unit. Output (q) 8000 9000 10000 Marginal profit 32.00 0 -14.00

Price 60.00

MC 37.00

Price = MC 60.00 89.00

Scientifical approach Market price : 60 Revenue Function : R = f(q) = pq = 60q Total Cost Function : TC = 0.000001q3 - 0.014q2 + 69q + 128'000

Output : q Fixed cost : 128'000 Variable cost : VC = 0.000001q3 - 0.014q2 + 69q

Tool to find "Total cost function" : Excel "Tools / Data analysis / Regression" Marginal Cost Function : MC = 0.000003q2 - 0.028q + 69 (derivated of the TC function)
16

Perfect Competition Economics of Competitive Markets

Huda Isa Al Mutawaj

201220199

Average Cost Function : AC = TC / q = 0.000001q2- 0.014q + 69 + (128'000 / q) Profit Function : Profit =(R - C) = 60q - ( 0.000001q3- 0.014q2 + 69q + 128'000 ) Profit = - 0.000001q3+ 0.014q2 - 9q - 128'000 Marginal Profit Function : Profit' = - 0.000003q2+ 0.028q - 9 (derivated of the Profit Function) Calculations

The profit of the competitive firm is maximum when Market Price = MC Price 60 = MC = 0.000003q2 - 0.028q + 69

For which output Price = MC ? ( P - MC ) = 0,000003q2 - 0,028q + 9 = 0 Formula to solve this equation :

Optimum output : 9'000 units

Results Maximum Profit 196'000

Optimum Output 9'000

Revenue Total Cost 540'000 344'000

Price MC 60.00 60.00

17

Perfect Competition Economics of Competitive Markets

Huda Isa Al Mutawaj

201220199

Figures

18

You might also like