You are on page 1of 11

BISE – STATE OF THE ART

Pricing Strategies of Software Vendors


Pricing strategies of vendors in the software industry have so far not been discussed compre-
hensively. This is surprising as the characteristics of the software industry differ particularly
from other industries. This paper provides an overview of pricing models for software. We
will take into account the characteristics of software as a product as well as the software
industry’s general conditions. Furthermore, we refer to recent software delivery models, such
as software as a service. The results are based on literature research and empirical studies.

DOI 10.1007/s12599-009-0075-y

The Authors ily be applied to software products (Bon- ing interviews with experts conducted in
tis and Chung 2000, p. 246). The reason November and December 2007 in order
is that the software industry is subject to to analyze the user perspective. We inter-
Dipl.-Wirtsch.-Ing. Sonja Lehmann
Prof. Dr. Peter Buxmann economic rules fundamentally different to viewed ten CIOs from companies deploy-
TU Darmstadt other industries (Buxmann et al. 2008a, ing standard application software for ERP.
Chair of Information Systems p. 1). For example, the software industry As this is an exploratory study, we chose
Hochschulstr. 1 is often characterized by network effects companies from different industries and
64289 Darmstadt (Shy 2001, p. 1) influencing the value of a of different sizes. In terms of size we inter-
Germany product for customers through its preva- viewed companies with 800 to 260.000
{lehmann | buxmann}@ lence rate (Katz and Shapiro 1985, p. 424). employees. The interviews were based on
is.tu-darmstadt.de This might cause lock-in effects on the a structured guideline.
customer side that also create new oppor- In the following sections we will first
Received: 2008-11-07 tunities with regard to pricing models. analyze the general conditions and char-
Accepted: 2009-03-02 Furthermore, we have to take into acteristics of the software industry which
Accepted after one revision account that software is offered or obtained are relevant to pricing. In section 3 we pro-
by Prof. Dr. Buhl. in various ways. With regard to the provi- vide an overview of the possible parame-
sioning of software, we can today observe ters of pricing models for software prod-
This article is also available in German an increasing trend towards on-demand ucts and their various characteristics. In
in print and via http://www.wirtschafts­ solutions besides traditional on-premise section 4 we present empirical results on
informatik.de: Lehmann S, Buxmann P software. In so-called software as a service the topic of software pricing models. The
(2009) Preisstrategien von Software- (SaaS) solutions the user purchases stan- paper concludes with a summary and an
anbietern. WIRTSCHAFTSINFORMATIK. dard software via the Internet without the outlook.
doi: 10.1007/11576-009-0197-3. need to install the software locally (Bux-
mann et al. 2008b, p. 500). In addition to
proprietary solutions also free and open 2 General conditions and
source software (FOSS) exists. As soft- characteristics of the
1 Introduction ware in business models of open-source software industry
software providers is usually free, in most
Pricing takes a central role in the strategy cases sales are realized by supplementary The design of a pricing model requires
of most companies (Simon 1992, p. 7; services, such as consulting, implemen- the consideration of the characteristics
Diller 2008, p. 21–22; Rullkötter 2008, tation, documentation, and maintenance of the product to be sold and the market
p. 93). It directly determines the turnover (Hecker 1999). As in that case the design conditions in the respective industry. As
level and thus in the long term also the of pricing models does not relate to soft- software is a digital good, the economic
achieved returns. In case of erroneous ware, we do not intend to dwell on this theory of digital products provides a first
decisions, the company’s reputation and type of software in more detail. starting point for the development of pric-
customer relations can be at risk. Despite Against this background, the aim of ing strategies for software providers.
this high importance, a multitude of this paper is to identify various funda- Fundamental characteristics of digital
deficiencies regarding pricing models can mental pricing models for software and goods are indestructibility, transmutabil-
often be identified, including rationality to examine their specific implications for ity, and reproducibility (Choi et al. 1997,
deficits in form of ad hoc or arbitrary the software industry. Moreover, we will pp. 69 ff).
decisions (Florissen 2008, p. 85). introduce the views of providers and users Indestructibility becomes apparent by
In this paper, we examine pricing strat- and their assessment of different pricing the unascertainable difference between
egies of software vendors. Traditional models. The results are based on literature new and used digital goods – there is no
pricing concepts, however, cannot eas- research and empirical studies, includ- loss of quality as a result of using the good.

452 Business & Information Systems Engineering 6 | 2009


BISE – STATE OF THE ART

Parameter of pricing models


for software products

Formation of Structure of Assessment Price Price Dynamic pricing


price payment flow base discrimination bundling strategies

Price Single payment Number of 1st Degree Offer Penetration


determination pricing pricing
components Pure bundling
Cost-based Mixed bundling
Value-based Unbundling
Competition- Usage-
oriented 2nd Degree Product Follow-the-free
Recurring dependent
strategy
Degree of payments Quantity Software
interaction Transaction
Time Maintenance
Frequency Memory
Unilateral requirements Versioning Service/Support
Duration Time
Interactive ... 3rd Degree Degree of Skimming
Combination integration strategy
Usage- Person-related
independent Complementary
Region-related
Substitutive
Named user
Independent
Concurrent user
Multi- Price Level
Machine, Server dimensoinal
CPU Additive
Key performance
indicators Superadditive
Fig. 1  Parameters of pricing mo- ... Subadditive
dels for software products

However, this does not exclude a possible software constitutes an experience good and Shapiro 1985): Direct network effects
loss of value over time (Zhang and Seid- whose actual value can be assessed by the arise because the users can communi-
mann 2003, p. 277). customer only after its purchase (Bux- cate with each other more easily and thus
As a result of the transmutability char- mann et al. 2008a, p. 137). more cost-effectively by means of sharing
acteristic, digital goods can be modified The possibilities of pricing for soft- software standards or common technolo-
with little effort allowing for a cost-effec- ware products are also determined by gies. In contrast, indirect network effects
tive generation of variants. This is particu- the Internet and its characteristics. Thus, result from the dependence between the
larly important in terms of price discrimi- the Internet can be used for the distribu- consumption of a basic good and the
nation strategies (cf. Section 3.4). tion of digital products (Albers et al. 2000, consumption of complementary goods
Reproducibility of digital goods is p. 80). This can significantly reduce dis- and services. Therefore, a high spread of
another important feature which may tribution costs and increase the potential standard software leads to an increasing
be considered in terms of pricing model clientele. In general, reduced transaction offer of consulting services, which in turn
design. Copying digital goods is possi- costs (Bakos 1998, p. 35) lead to a multi- results in a growing attractiveness of the
ble without a loss of quality and at low tude of new possibilities, such as a more software solution for the customers.
cost (Choi et al. 1997, p. 72). Software as flexible pricing model, new pricing mech- These network effects have a significant
a product is usually marked by relatively anisms, and billing systems for micro- impact on software markets and hence
high fixed costs for the software provider, payments. Furthermore, the easier inter- are reflected in the strategies of the soft-
while the costs for each additional unit action between customer and supplier is ware vendors. Thus, in many cases we can
tend to zero (Varian 1997, p. 1; Fishburn one of the Internet’s characteristics, e. g. in observe lock-in effects on software mar-
and Odlyzko 1999, p. 447). that it enables the implementation of reg- kets that lead to a solution which often is
However, it should be noted that these ular price changes with little effort (Skiera not technically optimal (Arthur 1996), and
characteristics of digital goods cannot be et al. 2005, p. 286). It is even economically therefore complicates the market entry for
transferred to all of the software providers’ possible to address every customer indi- competitors and binds customers to the
products (or components). In case of sup- vidually due to the Internet’s characteris- current provider due to switching costs
port and service offers, for example, sig- tics (Skiera et al. 2005, p. 286). (Shapiro and Varian 1999, p. 103–104).
nificant variable costs incur (Buxmann et Another feature of software markets Since frequently one supplier succeeds in a
al. 2008a, p. 111). In case of SaaS solutions, arises from the existence of network specific software industry segment, this is
for example, we have to take into account effects. This means that the value a soft- also referred to as “winner takes it all mar-
that the offer also includes the hosting and ware solution provides for a customer not kets” (Arthur 1996; Bakos 1998, p. 4). In
support services besides software provi- only depends on the properties of the solu- those areas of the software industry with
sion. This may partly result in significant tion, but also on the number of users. The less strong network effects the formation
variable costs. larger the network is, the better it usually of oligopolies results from the coexistence
In addition to these fundamental char- is for the user. We distinguish between of standards and companies (Skiera et al.
acteristics it is important to note that direct and indirect network effects (Katz 2005, p. 288). However, there is an ongoing

Business & Information Systems Engineering 6 | 2009 453


BISE – STATE OF THE ART

discussion whether SaaS solutions lead to For determining the price, basically tle sense economically (Shapiro and Var-
a reduced provider dependence. Reasons three forms are possible (Homburg and ian 1999, p. 23).
are especially seen in smaller customizing Krohmer 2006, p. 720; Nieschlag et al.
options as well as in the frequent use of 2002, p. 810–814): 3.2 Structure of payment flow
open standards. j cost-based
This possibly may result in a lower lock- j demand-driven or value-based, and When designing software pricing models
in effect for SaaS products. High switching j competition-oriented. there are basically two options: Either the
costs also arise from necessary changes in Following the approach of cost-based customer makes a single payment and
the organizational structure if software pricing, the price level is established using thus obtains perpetual rights of use for
and business processes are strongly linked. cost accounting (Diller 2008, p. 310–311). the software or the pricing model requires
Therefore, lock-in effects and switching For digital goods, however, this form of regularly recurring customer payments.
costs usually cannot be avoided even for price determination is of little importance Also the combination of the two variants
SaaS solutions in the field of enterprise because of their special cost structure. is possible (Kittlaus et al. 2004, p. 82).
software (Buxmann et al. 2008b, p. 501). Shapiro and Varian (1999, p. 3) summa- Single payments correspond to the
The above mentioned characteristics rize this as follows: “cost-based pricing widely used model of software licensing
and conditions are of high importance for just doesn’t work [...]. You must price your today. By purchasing a license, the cus-
the pricing of software products. There- information goods according to consumer tomer acquires a temporarily unlimited
fore, they have to be considered in partic- value, not according to your production right of use.
ular as regards the design of pricing strat- cost.” Therefore, cost-based pricing is not The possibilities in design of regularly
egies. suitable for software licenses. In contrast, recurring payments can be seen in both
price determination based on costs can frequency and in the duration of payments.
make good sense for SaaS. For example, customers and providers
3 Parameters of pricing models Demand-driven or value-based pric- can agree upon a monthly or annual sub-
for software products ing respectively is essentially based on scription price over a period of two years
the demand for the product (Homburg as a pricing model for using the software.
The design options for software products and Krohmer 2006, p. 720–721). Here, These pricing models are particularly fre-
are diverse. In the course of time, fun- the appreciation of the customers for the quent in SaaS solutions (Cusumano 2007,
damental changes in software pricing product is of importance instead of the p. 20) where customers use the provid-
models have occurred. While in times of product’s cost (Harmon et al. 2005, p. 1). er’s software during the period of pay-
mainframe computers pricing was usually For competitive price determination, ment (also referred to as subscription or
based on computing power, user-oriented the formation of prices is aligned to the rental models) via the Internet (Buxmann
pricing models (“licensing models”) have prices and the price-related behavior of et al. 2008b). From the user’s perspective,
become widely accepted in the recent past competitors (Homburg and Krohmer this pricing model has the advantage that
(Bontis and Chung 2000, p. 247–248). 2006, p. 747). The attractiveness of com- the software can be used economically for
Today, software vendors increasingly offer peting products for customers depends on short periods as the monthly payments
usage-based pricing models (Sundarara- the homogeneity of the products and the are usually less than a single payment for
jan 2004, p. 1660; Buxmann et al. 2008a, market structure among others (Nieschlag a software license (Cusumano 2007, p. 20).
p. 12–13). et al. 2002, p. 813). In the software indus- This advantage from the customer’s per-
Since there is no universal pricing model try, obtaining a large market share is of spective, however, entails greater finan-
for software providers (Bontis and Chung crucial importance for the providers due cial demands for the provider. Thus, SaaS
2000, p. 246) and pricing models may con- to network effects and the resulting lock-in providers often have difficulties yielding
sist of several elements, this paper provides effects on the customer side, especially if profitability for the company (Hill 2008,
different pricing parameters for software the product does not or only slightly differ p. 48). According to a survey of SIIA et al.
products. Fig. 1 shows the parameters of from the products of competitors. There- (2006, p. 5), U.S. software providers expect
the pricing models we are examining in fore, competitive pricing plays an impor- a greater distribution of subscription mod-
the following subsections. tant role for software products in addition els in future instead of single payments in
The software vendors’ pricing models to demand-based pricing. form of purchasing a license.
usually consist of a combination of differ- Another pricing parameter is the degree Moreover, also hybrid forms of single
ent parameters. The pricing model may of interaction. Non-interactive pricing is and regular payments are possible. For
also include several sub-points from each characterized by the unilateral determi- example, it is common to purchase a soft-
column. nation of the price by the provider with- ware license which is linked to a software
out the customer’s influence. In the case maintenance contract. This usually stipu-
3.1 Formation of prices of interactive pricing, the price results lates annual payments in the amount of a
from customer and supplier agreement. fixed percentage of the (single) license pay-
During the formation of prices the provid- Examples of interactive price formation ment. In current pricing models of many
ers settle how the level of prices should be are negotiations or (Internet) auctions (cf. software providers the maintenance per-
laid down. This requires considering the e. g. Schmidt et al. 1998). However, in most centage is about 20%. This model has the
basis of price determination on the one cases auctions for digital goods and there- advantage for the providers that payments
hand, and the degree of interaction on the fore also for software products make lit- will flow relatively steadily.
other.

454 Business & Information Systems Engineering 6 | 2009


BISE – STATE OF THE ART

3.3 Assessment base Tab. 1  Examples of a usage-dependent assessment base


Assessment base Description
Another design possibility is related to
Transaction The price depends on the number of transactions executed
determining the assessment base of the by the software. This can be a technical assessment base (e. g.
pricing model. This can be done e. g. per Web Service invocation) or an assessment base with regard
to contents (e. g. number of crawled delivery items).
user or in dependence on the utilized time.
It is also strongly linked to the customer’s Memory requirements The price is ascertained by units of memory requirements (e. g. per GB).
impression whether the pricing model of Time The amount of the price is determined by the actual
the provider is considered to be fair. duration of software usage (e. g. price per minute).
First, the number of price compo-
nents (Skiera 1999b) making up the pric- Tab. 2  Examples of a usage independent assessment base
ing model is fixed. Any price compo- Assessment base Description
nent is based on assessment. For exam- Named user The right to use the software is bounded to a specific
ple, the pricing model can be divided into person and therefore the price refers to a defined user.
a usage-independent basic amount to be Concurrent user This pricing unit allows the simultaneous use of the
paid monthly and in a usage-dependent software with a pre-defined number of users.
component, such as used storage capacity. Server/machine Customers will be charged for each server or machine. The
Skiera (1999b) was able to show that ser- rights of use are bounded to this server or machine.
vice companies can yield significant profit CPU The price of the software refers to the amount of CPUs in use.
improvements through the use of two
Master data The price of the software refers to the number of entered
price components compared to a pricing master data (e. g. customers, suppliers, employees,
model with only one price component. inventory, rental units, land parcels, managed assets).
As already indicated in the example, Locations The price applies per location. This includes
the assessment base can be either usage- special forms of locations (e. g. mines).
dependent or usage-independent. Basi- Produced amount The software is priced according to the production of
cally, a variety of parameters is possible the customer (e. g. produced barrels oil per day).
here. They may also be industry-specific, Key performance indicators The price refers to Key Performance Indicators
e. g. the number of managed rental prop- (e. g. revenue, expenses, budget).
erties can serve as assessment base for
software supporting the management of While SaaS solutions generally enable Price discrimination is particularly
apartments. many possibilities regarding the assess- important for providers of digital goods
Tab. 1 shows examples of a usage-depen- ment base, usage-independent variables, as it allows selling them to customers with
dent assessment base. such as the number of users, are widely a lower willingness to pay due to low vari-
The use of a usage-dependent assess- used. However, there are also some exam- able cost of digital goods. In addition, the
ment base can lead to fixed and variable ples of transaction-based pricing models simple and inexpensive modification of
administrative costs, for example for usage (Schwartz 2007, p. 6). digital goods promotes the application of
monitoring and billing. Even in the case Apart from its fundamental importance price differentiation strategies.
of low error rates in the creation of bills of the assessment base for the customers, Pigou (1929) distinguishes three forms
it should be considered that accounting the assessment base is necessary for price of price discrimination: price discrimina-
errors may lead to customer annoyance. discrimination. This will be examined in tion of first, second, and third degree.
This could possibly result in a decline of the following. In first-degree price discrimination
orders in the future (Sundararajan 2004, each customer receives a price offer in the
p. 1661). 3.4 Price discrimination amount of his/ her willingness to pay. In
A usage-independent assessment base is practice, e. g. in the software industry, the
constituted of variables that are not related Another parameter of software pricing is implementation of this type of price dis-
to the actual use of software. Tab. 2 shows price discrimination. Price discrimination crimination is difficult. The main reason
examples of a usage-independent assess- basically means offering the same prod- is the providers’ lack of detailed knowl-
ment base. ucts to different buyers at different prices edge of the customers’ willingness to pay
In support of usage-independent assess- (e. g. Diller 2008, p. 227; Skiera and Spann – in particular of each single customer
ment bases providers may argue that cus- 1998; Pepels 1998, p. 89). The provider’s (Choudhary et al. 2005, p. 1120).
tomers usually are willing to pay more for objective is an improved absorption of The second-degree price discrimination
the option of unlimited use (Sundarara- consumer surplus. Compared to a pric- plays an important role for digital goods
jan 2004, p. 1661). However, many cus- ing model with a standard price, this (Linde 2008, p. 209). It is based on the prin-
tomers overestimate their usage behav- can be achieved by taking into account ciple of self-selection, i. e. the customer
ior (Flatrate-Bias) (Lambrecht and Skiera a customer’s specific willingness to pay. decides which product-price combina-
2006, p. 221). In section four we will ana- When users identify different product tion he chooses (Varian 1997, p. 193). Ski-
lyze the question of usage-(in-)dependent benefits, the provider can realize higher era (1999a, p. 287) distinguishes between
pricing models again from the user’s per- total turnovers by differentiated prices
spective. (Diller 2008, p. 227).

Business & Information Systems Engineering 6 | 2009 455


BISE – STATE OF THE ART

quantity-, time-, and performance-related customers and at the same time incurr 3.5 Price bundling
price discrimination for this case1. increased efforts on the part of the supplier
For quantity-based price discrimina- (Viswanathan and Anandalingam 2005, Price bundling is another pricing param-
tion, the average price per unit changes in p. 269). As a result of extremeness aversion, eter for software products. In general,
accordance with the total quantity pur- i. e. the averseness to extremes, it is recom- price bundling is understood as the com-
chased. This also includes the flat rate as mended to offer three versions of informa- pilation of several identifiable sub-services
the average price per unit depends on the tion goods so that the customer can decide (products, services and/ or rights) of one
overall usage of the customer (Skiera and for the version in the middle as a compro- or more providers to a package of offers
Spann 2000). This kind of quantity dis- mise solution (Varian 1997, p. 200; Simon- (“Set”) with a specification of a total price
counts is widely used for software licenses, son and Tversky 1992; Smith and Nagle (Diller 2008, p. 240). Price bundling can
especially for key accounts. 1995). Bhargava and Choudhary (2008) also be considered as a special case of price
The time-based price discrimination suggest that companies should consider discrimination (e. g. Skiera et al. 2005,
is aimed at customers who are willing to further versions of lower quality in case of p. 290; Diller 2008, p. 240). As a result of
pay more or less at different points in time declining variable costs. The authors for- its high relevance for the software indus-
(Skiera and Spann 1998). Prices may, for mally show that with decreasing variable try, we will examine this issue of price
example, differ depending on the time costs versioning becomes advantageous for bundling for pricing of software products
of day or season. Prices for information providers. This is regarded as a result of the separately.
can also be differentiated according to gain of additional customers with a lower The objectives related to price bundling
the delay with which they are made avail- willingness to pay (Bhargava and Choud- vary. First and foremost, price bundling is
able for the customer (Skiera and Spann hary 2008, p. 1031). used for price discrimination (see section
2000). The third-degree price discrimination 3.4) (Viswanathan and Anandalingam
Another form of price discrimination is based on the supplier’s market segmen- 2005, p. 264). While conventional meth-
with self-selection is made up by perfor- tation (e. g. Diller 2008, p. 229). In con- ods of price discrimination require rather
mance-based price discrimination. This trast to second-degree price discrimi- detailed knowledge of the reservation
type occurs when relatively minor changes nation, customers cannot make a choice prices of individual products, this is nec-
are made in scope or quality of the offers on their own. The third-degree price dis- essary to a lesser extent for price bundling
(Diller 2008, p. 237). These product vari- crimination can be divided into personal (Adams and Yellen 1976, p. 476). Bakos
ants are offered at different prices. In the and regional discrimination (Skiera and and Brynjolfsson (1999) explain this with
context of product differentiation this is Spann 2000). the law of large numbers. Accordingly, it
also often referred to as versioning (Var- In the software industry personal price is easier for the vendor to forecast the will-
ian 1997; Viswanathan and Anandalin- discrimination is used e. g. in the case of ingness to pay for a bundle with a variety
gam 2005). lower prices for students or, more gener- of products than for each product individ-
Offering different versions of a product ally, for private use compared to licenses ually, as the willingness to pay distribution
is regarded as profitable particularly for for commercial purposes. For this form has a smaller number of extreme values for
digital goods as a result of their cost struc- of pricing a proof of identity is impor- the bundle (Viswanathan and Anandalin-
ture (Viswanathan and Anandalingam tant, such as by certificates in the soft- gam 2005, p. 264). Wu et al. (2008, p. 608–
2005, p. 269). Against the background of ware industry (Skiera and Spann 2000). 609) argue, however, that this is only appli-
network effects, inexpensive alternatives Different prices depending on the coun- cable when no variable costs occur; even
can lead to a greater market penetration. try as a form of regional price discrimi- if the variable costs are very low, signif-
This shows that software products gen- nation are particularly used for pricing of icant costs for a bundle with many ele-
erally exhibit good prerequisites for this consultancy services. ments arise and put the potential benefits
form of price discrimination (Bhargava In case of price discrimination in more of bundling into perspective.
and Choudhary 2008, p. 1029). Software than one dimension we speak of multidi- Especially in the software industry,
vendors often first develop a high quality mensional price discrimination (Skiera which is characterized by network effects,
and extensive product before removing and Spann 2002, p. 279). In practice, this is bundling can be beneficial for suppli-
certain features in order to be able to offer widely used. For example, a simultaneous ers as it supports a greater distribution of
different versions to the customers (Sha- regional and quantitative price discrim- (additional) products on the market. For
piro and Varian 1999, p. 63; Buxmann et ination is possible. In this case, the pro- example, the Adobe Creative Suite soft-
al. 2008a, p. 115–116). An example of per- vider has different prices for each country ware contains software for creating PDF
formance-related price discrimination or region in addition to a pricing model files in addition to photo editing and lay-
are the versions “Home Basic”, “Home depending on the sales volume. The aim out design. Therefore, the sales of the Cre-
Premium,” “Business”, and “Ultimate” of of multidimensional price discrimination ative Suite also foster the proliferation of
Microsoft Windows Vista which differ in is a finer segmentation of customers. This PDF documents. Furthermore, the bun-
terms of functionality and price. allows an improved absorption of existing dling strategy may impede the entry of
With regard to the number of versions, differences in willingness to pay. It should potential competitors (Nalebuff 2004), for
we have to take into account that a mul- be noted, however, that the complexity of instance of suppliers who just offer one of
titude of versions can be confusing for the pricing model should still be ascer- the products from the bundle. Moreover,
tainable for the buyer and billing should bundling may also serve the aim of sav-
1
Due to its minor importance in the
software industry search-related price remain feasible for the provider (Skiera ing costs in invoicing and delivery as mul-
discrimination was omitted. and Spann 2002, p. 279). tiple products are sold simultaneously in

456 Business & Information Systems Engineering 6 | 2009


N]Ühjgm\dqÜhj]k]fl
9mkaf]kkÜ­Ü@f^gjeYlagfÜJqkl]ekÜ<f_af]]jaf_Ü
©9@J<ªÜakÜl`]Üf]oÜh]]j¥j]na]o]\Ük[`gdYjdqÜÜ
]¥bgmjfYdÜ^gjÜl`]Ü]flaj]Ül][`fg¥][gfgea[YddqÜ
gja]fl]\Ü[geemfalqÜoal`ÜYÜ^g[mkÜgfÜ\]ka_fÜ
k[a]f[]¥gja]fl]\Üj]k]Yj[`‘Ü@lÜ[gflafm]kÜl`]ÜÜ
‚‡Üq]Yjk˜ÜljY\alagfÜg^Ül`]ÜbgmjfYdÜN@IKJ:?8=KJ¥
@E=FID8K@BÜZqÜl`YlÜYddÜYjla[d]kÜYhh]YjÜZgl`ÜÜ
PREPRINT afÜ<f_dak`ÜYf\ÜafÜ>]jeYf‘ÜDgj]gn]j–ÜYml`gjkÜ
International
Editorial Board
Z]f]xlÜ^jgeÜgmjÜ\gmZd]¥Zdaf\–Ü[gfkljm[lan]–ÜÜ
Editorial

Issue 1/2009:
Contents an
d Abstracts
Yf\ÜjYha\Üj]na]oÜhjg[]kk‘
d Abstracts
Contents an
Issue 2/2009:
Pa pe rs
Call for

›@ÜZ]da]n]Ül`]Ülae]ÜakÜghhgjlmf]Ü^gjÜl`]Ü@JÜÜ
[geemfalqÜlgÜhjgna\]Ükm[`Ügmld]lkÜ^gjÜ\]ka_fÜ
j]k]Yj[`]jk‘Ü9@J<–Ü`go]n]j–Ü`YkÜkge]Ümfaim]Ü
Y\nYflY_]kÜ^gjÜhgkalagfaf_Üalk]d^ÜYkÜYÜ\]kajYZd]Ü
rnal.org
www.bise -jou
FTSINFO RMATIK
l of WIRTSCHA
onal Journa
The Internati
gmld]lÜ^gjÜ\]ka_fÜk[a]f[]Üj]k]Yj[`‘šÜ
Ü 8dYfÜI‘Ü?]nf]j

ooo‘Zak]¥bgmjfYd‘gj_
BISE – STATE OF THE ART

Price bundling different products bundling may lead to


a more homogeneous demand structure.
Offer Product Degree of Price level Furthermore, bundling strategies tend to
integration be more advantageous the lower the vari-
Pure bundling Software Additive
Complementary able costs. Therefore, price bundling for
Mixed bundling Maintenance Superadditive
Unbudling
Substitive
Subadditive Fig. 2  Aspects of pri- software products is of particular inter-
Service/Support
Independent est. It is also worth noting that the opti-
ce bundling
mal number of products in a bundle may
also be determined by existing budget
one process (Viswanathan and Anandal- mentary (Diller 2008, p. 241) or, respec- constraints on the client’s side for exam-
ingam 2005, p. 264; Adams and Yellen tively, can substitute or be independent of ple (Bakos and Brynjolfsson 1999).
1976, p. 475–476). each other. Bakos and Brynjolfsson (1999)
In the following, we want to dwell on found that bundling a large number of 3.6 Dynamic pricing strategies
the aspects of price bundling as shown in unrelated information goods can be prof-
Fig. 2 before subsequently discussing the itable. Their model also allows the analysis Dynamic pricing strategies are based
factors influencing the advantages of bun- of complementary and substitutive bun- on a multi-periodic space of time. For
dling strategies. dle elements. the software industry, the penetration
Depending on the type of the software The bundle’s price may be determined strategy, the follow-the-free strategy, and
vendor’s offer, the three forms of pure in an additive, superadditive, or subaddi- the skimming strategy are of particular
bundling, mixed bundling, and unbun- tive method. In case of an additive bun- significance (Buxmann et al. 2008a,
dling can be distinguished. In the case of dle, the bundle price corresponds to the p. 122).
pure bundling, the products are offered sum of the individual prices. In case of The penetration strategy has the objec-
exclusively in a bundle. If the customer a superadditive package, the price of the tive to use low prices in order to maximize
can choose whether to buy the entire bundle is above the sum of the parts of market penetration (Dean 1950, p. 50).
bundle or the single products separately, the bundle, while a subadditive set has This is especially important for software
this is called mixed bundling. Unbun- a price below that amount (Diller 2008, vendors during market entry if alterna-
dling occurs when the customer can only p. 240–241). The last variant, i.e. a bun- tive software systems already have a large
purchase the products separately (Adams dle with discounts to individual prices, installed base (Buxmann 2002). At a later
and Yellen 1976; Schmalensee 1984, p. 212; is referred to as normal case (Diller 2008, stage – after reaching a critical mass – it
Olderog and Skiera 2000, p. 140). Another p. 241; Viswanathan and Anandalingam may be possible for the vendor to increase
variant is customized bundling which 2005, p. 264). Günther et al. (2007, p. 139) prices. Conditions for a sensible use of
allows the customer to choose within cer- found out in their study that the majority this strategy are the existence of network
tain specifications which of the products of respondents expect a lower total price effects and economies of scale as well as
should be contained in the bundle. The for the bundle when purchasing compos- switching costs (Skiera et al. 2005, p. 288).
vendor just determines the bundle’s price ite web services. For example, the price Ahtiala (2006) showed in experiments that
and scope (Hitt and Chen 2005). Wu and for the bundle of Microsoft Office is well against the backdrop of software piracy it
Anandalingam (2002) show that offer- below the sum of the individual prices of is beneficial for software vendors to ini-
ing several customized bundles can be its components. At the time when Micro- tially sell very cheap software to create a
beneficial for a monopolistic provider of soft delivered its operating system Win- lock-in effect and later offer upgrades at
information goods. Assuming incomplete dows as a bundle with the media player, a higher price. As a result of the low vari-
information, Wu et al. (2008) identified the customers had the impression that this able costs of digital goods and the exis-
that customized bundling is more prom- product was added for free. This form of tence of network effects and switching
ising for the provider than pure bundling bundling strategy can, for example, also costs, this strategy is widely used in the
or unbundling. be used to add new applications to older software industry. An example of a pene-
Another aspect of price bundling is the products in order to induce the customer tration strategy can be seen in high price
type of product. The partial offers of the to draw upon upgrade or maintenance ser- discounts for first time customers.
bundle can be quite different in nature. In vices (Cusumano 2007, p. 20). However, it In the case of the follow-the-free strat-
the software industry the product type will should be kept in mind that a bundling of egy, customers receive a product free of
primarily be the software itself, its main- products may be opposed to competition charge. The vendor’s objective is to create
tenance and service and support services. laws. An example of this is the European a lock-in effect on the users’ side in order
Today, the turnover of a software vendor is Commission’s proceedings against Micro- to generate revenues later on by means
typically separated into three equal parts soft because of the bundling of its oper- of complementary products or premium
of licenses, maintenance, and services ating system Windows with the Internet versions (Zerdick et al. 1999, p. 191–194).
(Cusumano 2007, p. 19). The offers from Explorer (Buxmann et al. 2008a, p. 30). For example, we can think of offering a
these three areas can be offered as a bun- On t he basis of Schma lensee’s software product free of charge while
dle in different forms. (Schmalensee 1984) studies, factors influ- the associated services, such as installa-
Furthermore, the products in the bun- encing the benefits of bundling have been tion, maintenance, training, and custom-
dle can also be described as regards their examined by Olderog and Skiera (2000) izing must be paid for (Cusumano 2007,
degree of integration. In this respect, par- among others. In the presence of a neg- p. 21). A prominent example from the
tial offers of the bundle can be comple- ative correlation of reservation prices for software industry is the strategy of the

458 Business & Information Systems Engineering 6 | 2009


BISE – STATE OF THE ART

Concurrent user 38%


58%

Machine / Server 48%


18%
37%
Named user 6%
14%
Usage-dependent 5%
23%
Processor core / CPU 4%
Key performance Software vendor Software user
Fig. 3  Assessment bases preferred indicators 1%
8%
by software vendors and users (SIIA
0% 10% 20% 30% 40% 50% 60% 70%
et al. 2006, p. 7)

software vendor Adobe who was able to tive, non-representative sample among Reasons for this were seen in the difficult
set the PDF standard with its free Acro- ERP users. forecast of the resulting costs as well as
bat Reader. While the software for read- The Software & Information Indus- in the potentially significant cost fluctu-
ing PDF documents has been given away try Association has conducted a survey ations due to different usage intensities.
to users for free, Adobe was able to gen- among 698 experts. They interviewed 487 In addition to the cost estimate, also the
erate revenues by selling the software for software vendors and 211 users (SIIA et determination of the assessment base was
creating PDF documents (Buxmann et al. al. 2006). Fig. 3 shows an overview of the classified as difficult. It was regarded as
2008a, p. 123–15; Cusumano 2007, p. 21). various licensing models and the extent essential for such a model that the mea-
Furthermore, basically also the skim- to which software vendors or users prefer suring effort should not be too large and
ming strategy might be used (after Dean these models. that the model is easy and understandable
1950, p. 49). Here, a rather high starting Pricing on the basis of concurrent for the user. With regard to its structure
price may be gradually reduced in the users is among the favorites of the users the model, however, partly corresponds to
course of time. The aim is to reach cus- as regards the possible usage-indepen- the conception of fairness of some respon-
tomers with a high willingness to pay first dent assessment bases for software prod- dents – these are willing to pay more for
and to skim consumers with lower reser- ucts (see also section 3.3). Moreover, also a high usage of the software in terms of a
vation prices later by a lower price (Bux- licensing based on servers or machine is value-based pricing model.
mann et al. 2008a, p. 125). In the software interesting for the user – with consider- The participants considered it to be
industry, this pricing strategy is infre- ably less popularity however. Only a few problematic that most of these models are
quently used, however. customers favor an assessment according structured in a way that the user pre-pur-
to the named user or processor. Just 1% of chases a usage quota. Quite often a sup-
the users support the assessment based on plementary payment becomes necessary if
4 Pricing strategies of software financial ratios, which thus constitutes the the actual use of the previously proposed
vendors – Empirical results least desired form (SIIA et al. 2006, p. 7). quota is exceeded. If the quota is not fully
In the following, we will also examine utilized, the user usually does not receive
In this section we will investigate how pricing models with a usage-dependent any refunds or credits.
different pricing and licensing models are assessment base in more detail as a key The users tend to negatively asses the
assessed by vendors and users. Since few result of the survey is that software ven- currently used pricing models of software
empirical results are available in this area, dors expect a greater dissemination of this vendors. One reason was seen in the com-
existing studies are usually based on just a model (see Fig. 4). plexity of pricing models, including their
few parameters of software pricing. The results also show, however, that combinations with each other. In this con-
Below we consider a study by the Soft- many users increasingly reject usage- text, the users also addressed their dissat-
ware & Information Industry Associa- dependent licensing models, as Fig. 5 sug- isfaction with IT outsourcing service pro-
tion from 2006, which only examines the gests. viders. In their opinion these tended to
parameters of the assessment base in rela- All in all, only a quarter of the custom- optimize their services according to tech-
tion to pricing. We supplement this study ers were satisfied with the pricing and nical criteria, which often lead to a “zoo of
with results of expert interviews with licensing strategy of the providers accord- licenses” on the customer side.
users conducted in 2007. Basically, it is ing to the SIIA study. One of the respondents expressed satis-
possible that an observation at different In the following, we will have a look faction regarding the conditions for large
times might have a distorting effect. From at the results of the expert interviews to enterprises. High discounts, however, were
our point of view, there are no influenc- obtain an idea of what reasons might make given only for licenses and not on mainte-
ing factors for the period from 2006 to late the user assess certain pricing models pos- nance fees. The reason for this can be seen
2007 that suggest a change of conditions itively or negatively. in the accounting rules. Software vendors
and therefore a distortion. The objective of Usage-dependent pricing models for balancing in accordance with U.S. GAAP
our consideration is to analyze the views software were only considered as an inter- must specify a so-called “fair value” for
of users and their backgrounds in greater esting alternative by three of ten respon- the realization of anticipated revenues for
detail. However, we have to keep in mind dents. Seven respondents expressed skep- multi-element arrangements (bundling)
that the interviews constitute a qualita- ticism to opposition for this pricing model. for outstanding maintenance services,

Business & Information Systems Engineering 6 | 2009 459


BISE – STATE OF THE ART

Concurrent user 5%

Machine / Server -3%

Named user 3%

Usage-dependent 12%

Processor core /CPU -1%


Fig. 4  Expected changes in the as-
Key performance indicators 6% sessment bases until 2008 from the
vendors’ perspective (SIIA et al.
-4% -2% 0% 2% 4% 6% 8% 10% 12% 14% 2006, p. 7)

Concurrent user 5%

Machine / Server -3%

Named user -1%

Usage-dependent -16%

Processor core /CPU -2%


Fig. 5  Change in user preferences
Key performance indicators -1% with regard to the use of different
assessment bases from 2005 to
-20% -15% -10% -5% 0% 5% 10% 2006 (SIIA et al. 2006, p. 7)

which can be reliably ascertained. For this required, although one IT manager also the user’s point of view, usage-indepen-
reason, these software vendors do not pro- noted the corresponding risks. When dent assessment bases, such as concur-
vide discounts on maintenance services using shorter usage intervals, the custom- rent users, are supported. On the other
(Suermann 2006, p. 112–114). ers are not bound as long as in case of clas- hand, usage-dependent variables, such as
Almost half of the respondents claimed sical outsourcing, for example. payment for transactions, are increasingly
more flexible pricing models in response being rejected. Software vendors, however,
to the question of which aspects of pric- expect a greater importance of the usage-
ing models should be modified from the 5 Summary and outlook dependent pricing models in future. In
user’s point of view. Here, the desired flex- order to assess the background of these
ibility refers to the periodic adjustment to In this paper, we presented and analyzed evaluations expert interviews were con-
the changing number of users, a tempo- different parameters of possible pricing ducted among users. The main reasons
rary usage (including “usage breaks”), models for software products, taking stated against usage-based pricing mod-
and new assessment variables regardless the economic specifics of the software els were the problematic cost calculation
of the number of users. However, it should industry into account. We examined the and the selection of a concrete, meaning-
be noted that flexible pricing models may six parameters formation of prices, struc- ful assessment base.
also be to the detriment of the customers ture of payment flow, assessment base, New forms of software provision, such
as the provider can use this flexibility for price discrimination, price bundling, and as SaaS, represent a new challenge for the
his own benefit. This is particularly pos- dynamic pricing strategies. In general, design of pricing models. Even if current
sible for ERP software since significant pricing models of software vendors can software offers for companies are primar-
switching costs can arise for changing the be attributed to a combination of these ily billed on a usage-independent basis,
provider. Consequently, it remains unclear parameters. For the software industry, also the application of usage-dependent
in the end who will benefit from flexible particularly the design of the assessment pricing models seems possible in this area.
pricing models. base is very specific. Here, units can either In this case, the assumption of negligible
Regarding the pricing of SaaS solutions, be determined depending on the usage variable costs cannot be maintained for
a usage-dependent assessment base (four of the software or usage-independently. SaaS providers as the fees usually include
consents) and a flat fee (five consents) were Moreover, low price and price bundling service and maintenance offers for the
proposed by the users. As an opportunity, strategies are often profitable because users on the one hand and on the other
the respondents mentioned the temporary of the low variable costs for software hand also have to provide server capac-
usage as well as the reduction of entry bar- licenses. ity. These costs are partly of a variable
riers or, respectively, the good predictabil- Based on a SIIA study among users and nature.
ity of costs in the flat fee model. In addi- providers we have analyzed assessments of When considering the pricing of SaaS
tion, a short period of cancelation was current and future pricing models. From providers we also have to take into account

460 Business & Information Systems Engineering 6 | 2009


BISE – STATE OF THE ART

Diller H (2008) Preispolitik, 4th edn. Kohlhammer,


that many software companies are plan-
Stuttgart
ning to in future offer SaaS solutions in Fishburn PC, Odlyzko AM (1999) Competitive pri- Abstract
addition to their product range (Lünen- cing of information goods: subscription pricing
donk 2007, p. 135). This is linked to the versus pay-per-use. Economic Theory 13:447– Sonja Lehmann, Peter Buxmann
so-called multi-channel problem, i. e. the 470
problem that the provider strategies also Florissen A (2008) Preiscontrolling – Rationalitäts- Pricing Strategies of Software
have to consider possible cannibalization sicherung im Preismanagement. Zeitschrift für Vendors
Controlling und Management 52(2):85–90
effects. For the vendor, this means that Due to the economic characteristics
Günther O, Tamm G, Leymann F (2007) Pricing
this aspect not only has to be considered in web services. International Journal of Business specific to the software industry, pricing
product design but also concerning pric- Process Integration and Management 2(2):132– concepts existing in other industries
ing strategies. 140 cannot be transferred without adapta-
Harmon R, Raffo D, Faulk S (2005) Value-based tion. Therefore, this article provides an
pricing for new software products: strategy in- overview of pricing models for software.
References sights for developers. http://www.cpd.ogi.edu/ In this context we discuss the six param-
MST/CapstoneSPR2005/VBSP.pdf. Accessed
eters formation of prices, structure of
Adams WJ, Yellen JL (1976) Commodity bundling 2009-03-10
Hecker F (1999) Setting up shop: the business of payment flow, assessment base, price
and the burden of monopoly. The Quarterly
Journal of Economics 90(3):475–498 open-source software. IEEE Software 16:45–51 discrimination, price bundling, and
Ahtiala P (2006) The optimal pricing of computer Hill S (2008) SaaS economics seem to favor users dynamic pricing strategies. Furthermore,
software and other products with high swit- more than vendors. Manufacturing Business we refer to recent software delivery
ching costs. International Review of Economics Technology Jan. 2008, p 48 models, such as Software as a service.
and Finance 15(2):202–211 Hitt LM, Chen P (2005) Bundling with customer The results are based on literature
Albers S, Clement M, Skiera B (2000) Wie sollen self-selection: a simple approach to bundling research and empirical studies.
die Produkte vertrieben werden? Distributions- low marginal cost goods. Management Science
Keywords: Pricing strategy, Software
politik. In: Albers S, Clement M, Peters K, Skiera 51(10):1481–1493
B (eds) eCommerce. Einstieg, Strategie und Homburg C, Krohmer H (2006) Marketingma- vendor, Software industry
Umsetzung im Unternehmen. 2nd edn. F.A.Z. nagement. Strategie – Instrumente – Umset-
Institut, Frankfurt am Main, pp 79–94 zung – Unternehmensführung, 2nd edn. Gab-
Arthur WB (1996) Increasing returns and the new ler, Wiesbaden
world of business. Harvard Business Review Katz ML, Shapiro C (1985) Network externalities,
74(4):100–109 competition, and compatibility. American Eco-
Bakos Y (1998) The emerging role of electronic nomic Review. Number 75:424–440
marketplaces on the internet. Communications Kittlaus H, Rau C, Schulz J (2004) Software-Pro-
of the ACM 41(8):35–42 dukt-Management. Springer, Heidelberg
Bakos Y, Brynjolfsson E (1999) Bundling informati- Lambrecht A, Skiera B (2006) Paying too much
on goods: pricing, profits and efficiency. Ma- and being happy about it: existence, causes,
nagement Science 45(12):1613–1630 and consequences of tariff-choice biases. Jour-
Bhargava K, Choudhary V (2008) When is versio- nal of Marketing Research 43:212–223
ning optimal for information goods? Manage- Linde F (2008) Pricing-Strategien bei Informati-
ment Science 54(5):1029–1035 onsgütern. WISU 2:208–214
Bontis N, Chung H (2000) The evolution of soft- Lünendonk T (2007) Führende Standard-Soft-
ware pricing: from box licenses to application ware-Unternehmen in Deutschland. Studie der
service provider models. Electronic Networ- Lünendonk GmbH, Bad Wörishofen
king Applications and Policy 10(3):246–255 Nalebuff B (2004) Bundling as an entry barrier.
Buxmann P (2002) Strategien von Standardsoft- Working Paper. School of Management, Yale
ware-Anbietern: Eine Analyse auf der Basis von University, New Haven
Netzeffekten. Zfbf 54:442–457 Nieschlag R, Dichtl E, Hörschgen H (2002) Marke-
Buxmann P, Diefenbach H, Hess T (2008a) Die ting, 19th edn. Duncker & Humblot, Berlin
Softwareindustrie: Ökonomische Prinzipien, Olderog T, Skiera B (2000) The benefits of bund-
Strategien, Perspektiven. Springer, Heidelberg ling strategies. SBR 52(2):137–159
Buxmann P, Hess T, Lehmann S (2008b) Software Pepels W (1998) Einführung in das Preismanage-
as a Service. WIRTSCHAFTSINFORMATIK ment. Oldenbourg, München
50(6):500–503 Pigou AC (1929) The economics of welfare, 3rd
Choi SY, Stahl DO, Whinston AB (1997) The econo- edn. Macmillian, London
mics of electronic commerce: the essential of Rullkötter L (2008) Preismanagement – Ein Sor-
doing business in the electronic marketplace. genkind? Zeitschrift für Controlling und Ma-
Macmillan, Indianapolis nagement 52(2):92–98
Choudhary V, Ghose A, Mukhopadhyay T, Rajan U Schmalensee R (1984) Gaussian demand and
(2005) Personalized pricing and quality diffe- commodity bundling. The Journal of Business
rentiation. Management Science 51(7):1120– 57:(1)211–230
1130 Schmidt C, Weinhardt C, Horstmann R (1998) In-
Cusumano MA (2007) The changing labyrinth of ternet-Auktionen – Eine Übersicht für Online-
software pricing. Communications of the ACM Versteigerungen im Hard- und Softwarebe-
50(7):19–22 reich. WIRTSCHAFTSINFORMATIK 40(5):450–
Dean J (1950) Pricing policies for new products. 457
Harvard Business Review 28:45–53 Schwartz E (2007) Calculating the cost of SaaS. In-

Business & Information Systems Engineering 6 | 2009 461


BISE – STATE OF THE ART

foworld, 2007-03-26, 6 logien – Electronic Commerce – Geschäftspro- strategies for information goods. Sadhana –
Shapiro C, Varian HR (1999) Information rules: a zesse. Gabler, Wiesbaden, pp 539–557 Journal of the Indian Academy of Sciences
strategic guide to the network economy. Har- Skiera B, Spann M (2002) Preisdifferenzierung im 30(2,3):257–274
vard Business School, Boston Internet. In: Schögel M, Tomczak T, Belz C (eds) Wu S, Anandalingam G (2002) Optimal customi-
Shy O (2001) The economics of network indus- Roadm@p to E-Business. Thexis, St. Gallen, zed bundle pricing for information goods. In:
tries. Cambridge University, Cambridge pp 270–284 Proceedings workshop on information techno-
SIIA, Macrovision, SoftSummit, SVPMA, CELLUG Skiera B, Spann M, Walz U (2005) Erlösquellen logy and systems, Barcelona
(2006) Key trends in software pricing and licen- und Preismodelle für den Business-to-Consu- Wu S, Hitt LM, Chen P, Anandalingam G (2008)
sing: a survey of software industry executives mer-Bereich im Internet. WIRTSCHAFTSINFOR- Customized bundle pricing for information
and their enterprise customers. http://www. MATIK 47(4):285–293 goods: a nonlinear mixed-integer program-
siia.net/software/pubs/SW_Pricing_ Smith GE, Nagle TT (1995) Frames of reference ming approach. Management Science
Licensing_Report.pdf. Accessed 2009-03-10 and buyers’ perception of price and value. Cali- 54(3):608–622
Simon H (1992) Preismanagement: Analyse, Stra- fornia Management Review 38(1):98–116 Zerdick A, Picot A, Schrape K, Artopé A, Gold-
tegie, Umsetzung, 2nd edn. Gabler, Wiesbaden Suermann JC (2006) Bilanzierung von Software hammer K, Lange UT, Vierkant E, López-Esco-
Simonson I, Tversky A (1992) Choice in context: nach HGB, US-GAAP und IFRS – Integrative bar E, Silverstone R (1999) Die Internet-Ökono-
tradeoff contrast and extremeness aversion. Analyse der Regelungen zu Ansatz, Bewertung mie: Strategien für die digitale Wirtschaft, 2nd
Journal of Marketing Research 29(3):281–295 und Umsatzrealisation von Software aus Her- edn. Springer, Heidelberg
Skiera B, Spann M (1998) Gewinnmaximale zeit- steller- und Anwendersicht. Diss. Universität Zhang J, Seidmann A (2003) The optimal soft-
liche Preisdifferenzierung für Dienstleistun- Würzburg. http://www.opus-bayern.de/uni- ware licensing policy under quality uncertain-
gen. ZfB 68:703–718 wuerzburg/volltexte/2006/1933. Accessed ty. ACM Press: Proceedings of the 5th internati-
Skiera B (1999a) Preisdifferenzierung. In: Albers S, 2009-03-10 onal conference on electronic commerce. New
Clement M, Peters K (eds) Marketing mit inter- Sundararajan A (2004) Nonlinear pricing of infor- York, pp 276–286
aktiven Medien. Strategien zum Markterfolg. mation goods. Management Science
F.A.Z. Institut, Frankfurt am Main, pp 283–296 50(12):1660–1673
Skiera B (1999b) Mengenbezogene Preisdifferen- Varian HR (1997) Versioning information goods.
zierung bei Dienstleistungen. Gabler, Wiesba- In: Kahin B, Varian HR (eds) Internet publishing
den and beyond: the economics of digital informa-
Skiera B, Spann M (2000) Flexible Preisgestaltung tion and intellectual property. MIT, Cambridge,
im Electronic Business. In: Weiber R (eds) Hand- pp 190–202
buch electronic Business: Informationstechno- Viswanathan S, Anandalingam G (2005) Pricing

462 Business & Information Systems Engineering 6 | 2009

You might also like