You are on page 1of 5

October 13, 2015

Labor Market Behavior during and after


the Great Recession: Has It Been
Unusual?
Murat Tasci and Caitlin Treanor

This summer marked the six-year anniversary of the


end of the Great Recession, one of the longest economic recessions, and possibly the worst, since the
Great Depression. What followed was a disappointingly feeble recovery, causing analysts to call into
question the fundamental relationship between the
labor market and the rest of the aggregate economy.
The phrase jobless recovery came into heavy use.
But has the relationship between the labor market and
the aggregate economy been so unusual during and
after the Great Recession? To answer that question,
we examine conditions in 11 different recessions and
the ensuing recoveries since the late 1940s. To gauge
the evolving relationship between labor markets and
the aggregate economy, we use two major indicators
of labor market conditionspayroll employment and
the unemployment rateand one for the aggregate
economyreal (inflation-adjusted) gross domestic
product (GDP).
Figure 1 shows the relationship between the decline in
GDP and employment for all 11 recessions. The size
of the bubbles represents the length of the recession
in quarters. As we would expect, greater losses in

Figure 1. Real GDP and Employment During


the Recession
Employment decline (percent)
6
5

2007-2009
1948-1949

Trend line with


most recent
recession
(R = 0.4235)

1981-1982

1957-1958

1953-1954

Trend line without


most recent recession
(R = 0.2024)

2
1990-1991

1
2001

1969-1970

1973-1975

1980

1960

0
-1
0.0

0.5

1.0

1.5

2.0

2.5

3.0

3.5

4.0

Real GDP decline from GDP peak to trough, percent

4.5

5.0

aggregate output led to a greater drop in employment.


The Great Recession saw GDP fall by 4.2 percent and
employment contract by 5 percent. This is the largest
drop in employment and GDP during any recession
since the late 1940s.
While these numbers are extraordinary in magnitude,
placing the Great Recession in the uppermost corner
of the chart, they are generally in line with the relationship between GDP and employment during previous
recessions. The two trend lines show the linear association between employment and GDP across recessions, one with and one without the last episode.
Bearing in mind that this linear relationship relies on
11 data points and is limited in its statistical significance, one can still see in this figure two features of
the Great Recession. The recession certainly elevated
the average employment loss associated with a given
level of contraction in GDP (the slope of the line with
the last episode is steeper than the line without). But
even then the Great Recession sits above the line that
includes it, showing that employment losses during
the Great Recession were disproportionately larger
than the historical norm among all 11 episodes. If
the Great Recession were on the line, its 4.2 percent
decrease in GDP would have been associated with
a smaller employment loss than what was observed.
Given the small number of observations and the modest R2 (showing the amount of the decline in employment explained by the decline in GDP), this does not
stand out as statistically significant, but it is nonetheless informative.
Figure 2 offers a similar analysis of the unemployment rate across all 11 recessionary episodes. Again,
there is an upward rotation in the trend line when
the Great Recession is included. We can also see
that the 20072009 bubble sits above that trend line,
indicating that, based on historical norms, the decline
in GDP would have been associated with a smaller
upsurge in unemployment than was observed.
Eradicating the job deficit once the recovery was
underway was a painfully slow process. This was true
one year into the recovery, and it remained true even
four years into the recovery. Figures 3 and 4 show
the average change in GDP that is associated with
improvements in employment and unemployment one
year into the recovery. The size of a bubble represents the drop in GDP during the preceding recession.
We expect to see a similar relationship between these
variables over the course of the recovery as they had
during the recessions, though with the opposite sign.

Figure 2. Real GDP and Unemployment


During the Recession
Unemployment rate increase (percent)
6
5
2007-2009

Trend line with most


recent recession
(R = 0.5031)
Trend line without
most recent recession
(R = 0.3031)

1973-1975
1948-1949

1953-1954
1969-1970

1981-1982
1990-1991

1957-1958

1980

1960
2001

0
0.0

0.5

1.0

1.5

2.0

2.5

3.0

3.5

4.0

4.5

5.0

Real GDP decline from GDP peak to trough, percent

Figure 3. Recovery in Real GDP and Employment:


One Year Out
Change in employment (percent)
10.0
1948-1949

8.0
Excludes most
recent recession
(R = 0.8942)

6.0
4.0

1973-1975
1957-1958
1969-1970
1960
1980
1981-1982
1990-1991
1953-1954
2001
Includes most

2.0
0.0
-2.0
-4.0

2007-2009

recent recession
(R = 0.9044)

14
4
6
8
Average quarterly change (annualized) in real GDP
from recession end to one year out (percent)

16

In fact, we find a tighter relationship between average GDP growth and improvements in labor market
measures within the first year of the recovery relative
to the recessions. For instance, every episode was
much closer to the trend line in figure 3 than it was in
figure 1.
Another interesting observation is that average GDP
growth per quarter varies a lot in the first year of the
recoveries. The recovery following the 19481949
recession saw an average of 13.5 percent growth,
whereas none of the last three recoveries averaged
more than 3 percent growth. In spite of this large
variation in the degree of GDP growth during recoveries, the relationship between GDP and employment
did not seem to change after the last recession; that
is, the trend lines did not change at all. The 2007
2009 recovery process was unusual only insofar as
GDP growth was weak, falling on the left-most side
of the graph along with the previous two recoveries.
Note that the three weakest recoveries have all followed the most recent recessions: 19901991, 2001,
and 20072009. In fact, payroll employment was still
falling a year after the start of the recovery in the first
two episodes.
Even though the term jobless recovery has been
used repeatedly for all three of these episodes, figure
3 makes it clear that what makes them jobless is not
their divergence from historical patterns as far as employment is concerned. Rather, it is the weakness of
the recovery in aggregate output. Note that this weakness does not seem to be an artifact of how severe
the preceding recession was. For example, the overall
GDP decline, peak to trough, was 0.3 percent in 2001
and 4.2 percent in 20082009, but both episodes
were followed by anemic recoveries: GDP grew only
2.3 percent and 2.7 percent, respectively, within the
first year. We see a similar picture for unemployment
in figure 4. Given that unemployment is generally
considered a lagging indicator, we hardly see a major
improvement within the first year of the recovery.
Figures 5 and 6 show the relationships between
GDP and employment and GDP and unemployment,
respectively, four years into the recovery. We exclude
recoveries in which a new recession began before
four years had passed, which leaves us with only 6
of our original 11 episodes. We see that the recovery
following the Great Recession still stands out as having the lowest GDP growth of all the recessions over
this longer period, a mere 1.9 percent per quarter on
average. After four years of recovery, the previous two
jobless recoveries looked much better than the Great

Figure 4. Recovery in Real GDP and


Unemployment: One Year Out
Change in unemployment (percent)
1.5
Trend line without most
recent recession
1.0
2001 1990-1991
(R = 0.9395)
0.5
1969-1970
2007-2009
0.0
1960 1957-1958
1980
-0.5
1953-1954
1973-1975
1981-1982
-1.0
-1.5
Trend line with most
recent recession
-2.0
(R = 0.9321)
-2.5
-3.0
-3.5
0
2
4
6
8
12
Average quarterly change (annualized) in real GDP
from recession end to one year out (percent)

1948-1949

14

Figure 5. Recovery in Real GDP and Employment:


Four Years Out
Change in employment (percent)
20
18
16

1973-1975

14
1981-1982

12
10
8

1990-1991

6
4

Trend line
without most
recent
recession
(R = 0.6729)

Trend line
with most
1960 recent
recession
(R = 0.6924)

2007-2009

2001

0
-2
1.0

1.5

2.0
2.5
3.0
3.5
4.0
4.5
5.0
5.5
Average quarterly change (annualized) in real GDP
from recession end to four years out (percent)

6.0

Recession, featuring growth rates of 3.1 percent and


3.3 percent. In some sense, what is different about
the Great Recession is that the recovery in aggregate
output started out weak and has never picked up.
In spite of that anemic growth, employment grew by
3.6 percent, roughly in line with the historical pattern.
On the other hand, the unemployment rate declined
by almost 2 percentage points, a substantially larger
decline than one would expect from a period of only
1.9 percent growth.
The Great Recession certainly had some unusual
features. It is an outlier in terms of the severity of the
recession and the sluggishness of the recovery. But
the labor markets behavior has not been that unusual, particularly in the recovery phase. While the recession saw a larger employment loss and a larger unemployment rise than would have been predicted by the
decline in GDP, the recovery has seen improvement in
these indicators that is completely in line with historical patterns. The Great Recession, like most recent
recoveries, has been particularly anemic, and thats
the real problem. The question is not why or how the
link between labor markets and output has changed,
but why growth after recessions has become so
feeble compared to that of earlier times.

Figure 6. Recovery in Real GDP and


Unemployment: Four Years Out
Change in unemployment (percent)
1.0
0.5
2001

0.0
-0.5

1990-1991

-1.0

1960
-1.5

2007-2009

-2.0
1973-1975

-2.5
-3.0
-3.5
1.0

1981-1982
1.5

2.0

2.5

3.0

3.5

4.0

4.5

5.0

Average quarterly change (annualized) in real GDP


from recession end to four years out (percent)

Trend line
with most
recent
recession
(R = 0.2254)
Trend line
without most
recent recession
(R = 0.5985)

5.5

6.0

Murat Tasci is a research economist in the Research Department of the Federal Reserve Bank of Cleveland. He is primarily interested
in macroeconomics and labor economics. His current work focuses on business cycles and labor markets, labor market policies and
search frictions.
Caitlin Treanor is a research analyst in the Research Department of the Federal Reserve Bank of Cleveland. Her primary interests
include development economics, macroeconomic policy, and applied econometrics.
Economic Trends is published by the Research Department of the Federal Reserve Bank of Cleveland.
Views stated in Economic Trends are those of individuals in the Research Department and not necessarily those of the Federal Reserve
Bank of Cleveland or of the Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System. Materials may be reprinted provided that the source is
credited.
If youd like to subscribe to a free e-mail service that tells you when Trends is updated, please send an empty email message to
econpubs-on@mail-list.com. No commands in either the subject header or message body are required.
ISSN 0748-2922

You might also like