You are on page 1of 18

See

discussions, stats, and author profiles for this publication at:


https://www.researchgate.net/publication/248881282

The Geographical Transfer of


Value: Notes on the
Spatiality of Capitalism
Article in Environment and Planning D Society and Space January
1984
Impact Factor: 1.92 DOI: 10.1068/d020329

CITATION

READS

14

1 author:
Costis Hadjimichalis
Harokopion University of
71 PUBLICATIONS 433
CITATIONS
SEE PROFILE

Available from: Costis Hadjimichalis


Retrieved on: 01 May 2016

Environment nncJ Plonnlnfj D: Society nnd Spnco, 1904, volumo 2, pngos 329-345

The geographical transfer of value: notes on the


spatiality of capitalism1'
C Hadjimichalis
School of Technology, University of Thossaloniki, University Box 491, Thossaloniki, Grooco
Rocolvod 21 April 1983; In revised form 14 March 1984

Abstract. Marxist research on the geographical unovenness of capitalist development remains highly
heterogeneous. Although virtually all Marxists agree on certain general concepts, such as capital
accumulation, agglomeration in space, spatial division of labor, capital mobility, the role of the
state, etc, there is strong disagreement on how these processes operate and on the nature of their
impact on various places. In this paper, a critical evaluation of two dominant lines of thought, the
autonomous or semiautonomous development thesis and the transfer-ofsurplus-development thesist
is presented, A third approach, based on the notion of the geographical transfer of value, an
attempt to use the labor theory of value in geographical terms, is also introduced. This view is
further elaborated by focusing first on the articulation of production and circulation, second on
state and local state intervention in this articulation, and third on the contradiction between
equalization and differentiation. Throughout the paper, a special emphasis is given to the
determinant role of class struggle and to the absence of any 'iron laws of motion of capitalism*.
1 Introduction
The geographical unevenness of capitalist development has many sources. Our
inability to distinguish among separate forces operating simultaneously is to a large
extent responsible for the present confusion surrounding the question of uneven
development over space.
In this paper, in which I synthesize some of the ideas contained in a forthcoming
book (Hadjimichalis, forthcoming), I aim to challenge the current understanding of
the relationship between the Marxian theory of value, development, and space.
More specifically, I will try to go beyond immediate appearances of geographical
phenomena by investigating their underlying mechanisms and tendencies. To begin
the analysis with issues such as capital mobility, agglomeration in space, spatial
division of labor, development of productive forces, etc is a necessary, but too
elementary, approach. Instead, I will try to use the labor theory of value in
geographical terms, in a framework dominated until recently by aspatial categories
and processes. In so doing, I propose an alternative framework for possible future
research in the field, based on the notion of the geographical transfer of value (GTV).
Taken singly, the ideas presented here are not entirely original. Indeed, my work
is influenced by, although I am not in agreement with them, theorists such as
Gramsci, Lefebvre, Emmanuel, Shaikh, Lipietz, Soja, de Janvry, Cooke, and others.
This paper could be described as an effort to make explicit the influence of certain
conditions which are 'space-specific' and 'particular to a location' in the production,
circulation, and realization of surplus value. I am aware that GTV is or could be a
very controversial issue. Its association with the Marxist theory of value and 'surplustransfer theories' (in particular, unequal exchange), and its dialectical focus on sociospatial processes, could make it highly vulnerable to the criticisms of neo-Ricardians,
unequal exchange critics, and to those who still approach space as a simple and
t An earlier version of this paper was presented at the workshop on 'Capital Restructuring and the
Regional Question* in Copenhagen, May 1982, and at the '29th North American Meeting of the
Regional Science Association' in Pittsburg, November 1982.

330

C Hadjimichalis

passive container of productive forces. I will try to defend my thesis, first by


focusing on the articulation of production and circulation, and second by arguing for
the important role of class struggle and the state inscribed in this articulation.
2 Autonomous versus transfer-of-surplus-development theories
During the 1960s and 1970s, Marxist research on the geographical unevenness of
capitalist development succeeded in establishing itself as an alternative analytical
framework to neoclassical and liberal theories. Initially built upon general laws and
abstract formulations, approaches 'borrowed' from international development theories,
and theories of capital accumulation, geographical analysis using Marxist tools and
methodology was and remains highly heterogeneous (Massey, 1978; Soja, 1983).
Though virtually all Marxists call upon these processes to explain uneven development
between firms, sectors, and regions, there is strong disagreement on how such
development operates and on the nature of its impact on various places. With the
risk of oversimplifying, I will identify two dominant lines of thought within this
heterogeneous intellectual tradition.
The first, based on the process of capitalist production, addresses the self-expansion
of capital and puts forward the autonomous or semiautonomous development thesis.
In this case, different geographical areas (however defined) grow or decline depending
on concretely different production processes and types of product manufactured by
firms located in these areas, and on different use-value circumstances of capital and
labor operating in these places (Harvey, 1975; Walker, 1978). Development is
dependent upon the putting together of the necessary conditions for profitable
accumulation (mainly via exports). Sectoral composition and dynamics are major
causal forces shaping regional differentiation (Markusen, 1983). This line of thought
originates from Lenin and Bukharin, who centered their analyses of uneven
development on the contradictions of accumulation that exist within certain capitahst
areas (Lenin, 1973; Bukharin, 1973). In their view, it is possible for various
capitalist sectors to grow relatively autonomously from other sectors: this offers
local investment opportunities for capital, but also leads to the accumulation of
enormous masses of capital that drive down the rate of profit. As Lenin (1973,
pages 73-74) observed, "... surplus capital then seeks 'your areas' external to the
capitalist sphere: in these areas profits are usually high, for capital is scarce, the price
of land is relatively low, wages are low, raw materials are cheap". This combination of
different rates of profit in different areas is also analyzed by Harvey (1975), who
uses Marx's concept of the 'annihilation of space by time' to emphasize capital's goal
to lower its time of circulation and to speed its self-expansion. In an attempt to use
the profit-cycle model, Markusen (1983) argues that super profits in certain firms
are a return to capitalists resulting from lower production costs (socially necessary
labor time) or from the reduced time a household spends in reproducing labor power.
Along similar lines, Lapple and van Hoogstraten (1980) suggest that the 'fundamental
causes of unevenness' are the continuous expansion of surplus-value production and
the increase of productivity, all occurring within the same firm at the same place.
Similarly, Webber (1982) argues that the regional question concerns the spatially
uneven development of branches of production, with agglomeration economies
providing the immediate cause of such uneven development.
Four serious weaknesses are identifiable in the autonomous approach to uneven
geographical development. First, although it focuses on accumulation, it denies the
importance of circulation and exchange. Rather, production is the driving force for
development, and anything else is subordinate to it. Second, and unsurprisingly,
regional development is conceived as an outcome of the autonomous growth of local
productive forces only, thus denying any relationship between sectors and firms in

Tho fincwjrnphical transfer of value

331

different geographical units in the outside world, Third, because the main focus of
abstraction is upon the logic of production and accumulation, there is little reference
to the role of class mobilization, political action, and the state, And fourth, there is
a tendency to regard everything that occurs in space and time as conducted on behalf
of capital, ending either in cyclical arguments or in economic rcductionism.
The second approach places major emphasis upon the sphere of capital circulation
and exchange, ignoring (in some cases) production relations. Through circulation and
exchange, surplus produced by workers in some areas ('the periphery*) is extracted
and transferred (via a number of mechanisms) to benefit capitalist development in
other sectors and areas ('the core*). This approach is called the tramfer-of-surplmdevelopment thesis (Amin, 1978; Baran and Swcezy, 1970; Emmanuel, 1969;
Liossatos, 1979; Lipictz, 1977), Development is said to be dependent on the
strength (economic and political) of the core's social classes, which are able to
accumulate wealth and power while the periphery is 'drained* via surplus transfer.
Bauer (1924) was a direct supporter of the surplus-transfer thesis, arguing (against
Lenin and Bukharin) about the appropriation of surplus value from less-developed
areas in cases where these areas have less capital* compared to developed areas. Four
years later, in 1928, Kuusinen, at the 6th World Congress of the Comintern, defended
a thesis that capitalist penetration in the periphery of the world system under the
aegis of imperialism was not only a source of surplus extraction to the benefit of the
center, but also created a 'bottleneck* to industrialization and resulted in stagnation
(Kuusinen et al, 1973). After World War II, these ideas acquired wider theoretical
legitimacy both through the work of Baran and Sweezy (1970) and through the
'development-of~underdevelopment*, 'dependency*, and 'core-periphery* schools of
thought (Carney et al, 1975; dos Santos, 1970; Frank, 1969). The surplus-transfer
concept, however, gained its major theoretical status through the writings of the
Greek Marxist economist Emmanuel (1969) in his book on 'Unequal Exchange* and
through the long debate that this book sparked off. Emmanuel distinguishes three
forms of unequal exchange: first, unequal exchange in the 'broad sense', when only
differences in the organic composition of capital exist; second, unequal exchange in
the 'narrow sense', with differences only in wages; and third, unequal exchange in the
'strict sense*, with differences both in organic composition and in wages. Amin
(1978), Emmanuel (1969), and Mandel (1975) are aware that, within a given social
formation, redistributive mechanisms could wipe out the inequality of exchange.
This seems, however, a very optimistic expectation, as the research of Lipietz (1977),
Liossatos (1979), Ferrao (1982), Perrota (1981), and Bajec (1983) has shown. Interregional polarization develops as extroverted, as opposed to introverted, accumulation
is taking place, or as differences between the organic composition of capital and of
labor increase.
The main problem with these accounts of uneven geographical development is their
incomplete abstraction of the determinants of the processes to be explained. First,
there is an overemphasis on the sphere of circulation and exchange, contrary to the
autonomous development thesis. Second, their prediction of a continuous 'underdevelopment or stagnation' of the periphery through surplus transfer was simply
wrong, as international and regional experience has shown. Third, they use an
unclear definition of exploitation via external factors and exchange, thus ignoring
local social relations and class struggle. This rests upon a mainly technological
explanation of the sources of increased productivity and, hence, of wage increases.
Fourth, they assume equilibrium in the capital market (internationally and nationally),
which implies that capital movements (the more mobile factor) have already resulted
in a world or regional equalization of the rate of profit. And fifth, some of the
authors, adopting a functionalist categorization between core and periphery, failed to

332

C Hadjimichalis

identify social classes within particular areas, thus arguing indirectly about place
exploiting place.
It seems, therefore, that although considerable progress has occurred in the
theorization of the process of uneven geographical developmentbecause of a deeper
understanding of the underlying processes associated with capital accumulation and
circulationthat such progress may be undermined by an emerging dogmatism in the
two dominant lines of thought. Struggling to be serious and rigorous in their
application of Marxist methods, many (on both sides) began to establish certain
boundaries beyond which a Leftist analysis could not reach. The process seems to be
analogous with what Soja (1980, page 208) has described in his analysis of the sociospatial dialectic:
"... instead of sensitively probing the mix of opposition, unity and contradiction
which defines the socio-spatial dialectic, attention has too often been drawn to the
empty question of which causes which or to endless arguments about preeminence".
Instead of focusing upon a fundamental linear idea of capital accumulationeither
autonomously or via surplus transferI propose a third view, which focuses both
upon production and exchange and upon local social classes and the state. Theories
which treat exchange as the dominant source of exploitation and the principal factor
of development in regions have been found inadequate. However, it has also been
seen that a focus on production requirements and accumulation imperatives, to the
exclusion of exchange relations, tends to be closely associated with an inappropriate
economic reductionism (Cooke, 1983).
What must be clearly demonstrated then is how and in what ways production,
circulation, and exchange relations connect accumulation to specific localities, and
whether a relation could be established among these localities based on the labor
theory of value. Before I pass to this level of analysis, a short comment on the
labor theory of value and the unity of production and circulation is necessary.
3 A short comment on the labor theory of value and the articulation of production
and circulation
The debate on whether Marx's labor theory of value (LTV) is necessary in the
analysis of capitalism, and whether it is irreconcilable with the actual relations
involved, is an old one. It has acquired great popularity through Sraffa's (1960) work
and more recently through that of Steedman (1977) and the neo-Ricardian school.
Initially confined to a relatively narrow grouping of economists, the controversy
about value theory has spread to wider circles on the left. It is beyond the scope of
this paper to provide a detailed review of the ongoing debate. Instead I will highlight some of the points relevant to the discussion of the geographical transfer of
value (GTV).
Theories adopting the Sraffian perspective argue that profits can be considered as a
direct consequence of only two factors: the sociotechnical conditions of production
and the real wage paid to workers. Other factors of profit have an effect only by
virtue of their influence on these two factors. This argument is based on a
mathematical analysis of the necessary conditions for formally calculating profits from
a set of initial conditions. The categories of the LTV, neo-Ricardians argue, do not
enter into this calculation at all (Hodgson, 1981; Steedman, 1977).
The critical point of this model, as Wright (1978) maintains, is not only to reduce
the theory of profits into a simple two-factor account, but rather to argue that other
causes have their effect on profits via real wages and technical conditions. Thus
class struggle, political conditions, the state, ideological hegemony, andas I go on to
argue laterspace could not have effects on aggregate profits. In accordance with
Wright's criticism, Shaikh (1980; 1981) emphasizes the fact that if one's interest in

Tho gooorophicnl transfer of voluo

333

studying profits is limited to calculating profits, then the nco-Ricardian level of


abstraction is as far as one needs to go, This is evident, for example, in Scott's
(1980) otherwise very interesting attempt to use nco-Ricardian concepts in studying
urban land. Scott adopts Stccdman's approach in treating real wages as exogenously
determined if the economy is to yield determinate prices and profits, But Scott fails
to recognize that problems such as the spatial differentiation of the rate or profit,
capital polarization in space, and changes in urban land (location, distribution, etc)
are not restricted to technical changes only.
If, on the other hand, one's interest is in understanding the social determinants (or
structural limitations, according to Wright (1981)) of profits, one needs to move to a
higher level of abstraction. This is precisely what the Marxist model of profit
determination attempts, using the LTV. As Lipietz (1981) recently proved, the
concept of value, including the magnitude of value, illuminates the whole qualitative
and quantitative analysis of price relations, uncovering relationships where the neoRicardians see merely discrepancies.
An important problem, which is directly related to my discussion of GTV, is the
failure of neo-Ricardians to make the distinction between value and realized value.
This rests on their inability to recognize the difference between abstract labor and
socially necessary labor (compare Himmelweit and Mohum, 1978). Marx (1976;
1981), on the other hand, is explicit about this difference in Capital (Volumes 1 and 3),
where he makes a clear distinction between use-values produced for direct use and
converted into commodities only when exchanged, and use-values produced for
exchange and hence produced as commodities (Shaikh, 1981). Indeed, exchange is a
process in which the different labor-times involved in producing these use-values
actually confront each other and are eventually articulated into a social and spatial
division of labor through the medium of money prices. But can we say that the mass
of surplus value gets bigger or smaller depending only on relative money prices?
Shaikh (1981, page 300) answers this as follows:
"... consider a crisis in which so little of the social product is sold that profit is
actually negative (this is a recurrent real phenomenon in capitalism). Are we then
to say that even though workers were exploited and a surplus product produced
surplus-value is itself negative? If we are not allowed recourse to the distinction
between value produced and value realised, then of course surplus-value is no longer
connected to any rate of exploitation at all. It is merely an epiphenomenon of
circulation. And so what begins as a tactical capitulation to the neo-Ricardians
turns into a rout".
Shaikh's interpretation points directly to the articulation of production and
circulation. Such an articulation derives from the fact that, after the act of
production, surplus value is embodied in the value of commodities that must
circulate (that is, be sold) for surplus value to be realized as money and for capital
to grow. In this competitive context, the necessary relation between production and
circulation is also contradictory: circulation is the negation of production, and
production is the negation of circulation (de Janvry, 1.981; Lipietz, 1983). The
essence of economic crises is to a large extent found in this contradictory relationship.
The class nature of capitalism implies the existence of interclass and intraclass
conflicts regarding the production and distribution of economic surplus and, in
particular, the determination of profit made by capitalists, versus their costs. Moved
by the profit motive and class conflicts, capital is thus driven to expand in the sphere
of production, and simultaneously encounters a barrier in the sphere of circulation
(Harvey, 1983). The articulation and contradiction between production and
circulation results in the periodic emergence of unsold commodities, the selling of
commodities below their value, or an increase in circulation time.

334

C Hadjimichalis

Thus the concept of value cannot be seen as a production theory, as in the neoRicardian interpretations, since in the absence of circulationthat is, of sale and
exchangethere is no creation of value at all. The transformation of private into
social labor occurs only through exchange (de Vroey, 1981). On the other hand,
however, this is not a pure circulation-exchange theory, because once there is a sale,
and thus a creation of value, the magnitude of value depends on the average social
conditions of production prevailing at the place of production. Exchange creates
value, but social production determines the magnitude of value.
4 The state and the local state
In this section, I present a condensation of a short theoretical analysis of the relationship between the state and capitalist spatial development. The parts of the argument
which are exposed here focus on the particular role of state intervention, mainly in
the spheres of circulation and reproduction.
I pointed out in section 2 that one major inadequacy of autonomous and transferof-surplus-development theories was their limited concern with the state and the local
state, when the latter exists as part of an elected administration system. In a number
of theories, the state is viewed as an instrument in the hands of the capitalist class.
It seeks to manipulate workers' resistance, capital demands, natural resources, etc
through specific policies to the benefit of capital (Miliband, 1974; Toft Jensen,
1982). Close to this instrumentalist view is the state-monopoly-capital thesis
(Boccara, 1971; Cherpakov, 1969). In this, the modern capitalist state, after the
evolution of some internal laws, has passed from the competitive to the monopoly
stage of the economy and is now totally dependent on big monopoly capital. Central
and local state policies are mainly oriented to secure high rates of profit for monpoly
capital, both nationally and internationally (Damette, 1980; Lojkine, 1977).
Without adopting the simplicity of instrumentalist and state-monopoly-capital
theories, capital-logic theories view the state as a 'fictitious collective capitalist', the
principal role of which is to respond to capitalist interests (Alvater, 1973). The state
is mainly responsible for the material reproduction of the means of reproduction in
order to secure social cohesiveness and to promote international expansion for national
capital. Contrary to the previous theories, capital-logic theories allow for a certain
autonomy of the local state derived from its conflict-diversification function performed
on behalf of the central state (Cooke, 1983; Dear and Clark, 1981; Hirsch, 1981).
But they share similar problems with instrumentalist and state-monopoly-capital
theories: they read social action through purely economic categories. These views
have been criticized for their inadequate theorization of the class character of the
capitalist state and for their functionalist and reductionist vision of capitalist
development (Cooke, 1983; Poulantzas, 1978; Urry, 1981). As such, they require a
holistic concept of civil society to overcome their tendency to reduce political
relations and actions to economic relations and decisions.
The idea that civil society has a specificity of its own which assists the structuration
of political action in particular localities is first found in the work of Gramsci (1971;
1973; 1975). Gramsci elaborated a new conception of hegemony and civil society
and was able to break with permanent duahsm and economism, expressing thereby an
appropriate emphasis on the political. In his emphasis on the 'ensemble of relations',
Gramsci's critique of what he called 'absolute historicism' focused attention on the
political, ideological, and cultural problems of capitalism and upon the role of the
state. These problems were concretized in time and space, in history and geography
the indispensable conjunctural framework, or the material basis upon which
revolutionary strategy had to rely. As Paggi (1979) argues, Gramsci represents both
a continuity and a rupture with Leninism. On the one hand, he extends Lenin's

Thu ooorjniphicnl tninnfor of value

335

major argument that history does not proceed via a simple functional logic and that
every articulation and radical change depends on a political intervention by the
revolutionary subject. On the other hand, he does not confine the primacy of the
political to revolutionary conjunctures only, but makes it the articulatory principle of
every social situation.
It is precisely this Gramscian notion of the political as the articulatory principle
that lies at the heart of the present problem of uneven geographical development in
most European countries. Such a conjuncture is better theorized in the so-called
4
class theories' and nco-Gramscian theories of the state (Dulong, 1976; Glucksmann,
1979; Laclau, 1977; Offe, 1974; Poulantzas, 1976; 1978). In these two
approaches, the local state is not conceived as a simple agent of the central state,
subject to its mandate and sharing its burden of administration. The local state may
at certain times experience autonomy, but is constrained by the limits which local
and 'national' class relations both impose (Dulong, 1976). The state, in the latest of
Poulantzas's (1979) interviews, is itself a relation, and (to be more precise) the
condensation of class relations. It is neither an 'entity' on its own, nor totally a part
of modern capitalist society; it is a field of class struggle, a product and a determinant of
contradictory social and spatial relations.
In the neo-Gramscian tradition, further emphasis is given to the role of ideological
hegemony as a means of securing the cohesivencss of the capitalist system (Laclau and
Mouffc, 1981). In these theories, the local state could become separate from the
central state when the former is not reproducing capitalist hegemony. Dominant classes
must secure the acceptance of the existing mode of exploitation by dominated classes
through a continuous displacementin time and spaceof popular demands. These
demands could produce a series of crises, which could vary from particular crises
(such as a legitimation crisis, a representation crisis, a regional crisis, etc) to the more
general crisis of the state itself (Poulantzas, 1976).
These two theories, and especially the neo-Gramscian view, provide us with an
important distinction between the economic, the political, and local civil society. It
is precisely the difficulty of making the separation, and, at the same time, the
connection among these three categories, that relates the local state with capitalist
development. As I discussed in the previous section, the unity between production
and circulation (or exchange) rests upon the nature of the commodity form, which
only releases the surplus value it contains when that value has been realized on the
market. The nature of the relationship between labor and capital is one of exchange:
surplus value is 'injected' by workers into the commodity at the point of production,
but labor receives less than this in the form of wages.
The sphere of production relations per se is an area into which the state, either
central or local, has the greatest difficulty in intervening. When it does so, it is
always a reflection of class struggle, and usually takes the form of an indirect intervention, mainly via legislation. The state and the local state, however, do respond
directly to pressure from capital and/or labor in the sphere of circulation and
reproduction, of which exchange is a part. The clearest examples of this are those
aspects of policy which can be broadly included under headings such as regional
incentives to capital and labor, agency assistance, zoning, means of collective
consumption, and physical infrastructure. Certain implications of these spatially
differentiated components of circulation and reproduction are considered in the next
section. For the moment, it is necessary to emphasize that the growing state intervention in circulation and reproduction changes the whole process of indirect regulation
performed by the LTV. This requires a modern conceptualization of the LTV to
account for cases in which the state (through price regulation, norms of exchange, or
special trade legislation) could weaken or strengthen the 'pure' LTV (Wright, 1981).

336

C Hadjimichaiis

Though the commodity system remains anarchicthere is no explicit and direct


allocation of social labor and of the means of productiona certain social cohesion
is required to ensure the reproduction of capitalist relations. This occurs through
a posteriori norms via the LTV and through contradictory policies introduced by the
state and the local state.
5 The contradiction of equalization and differentiation
During the process of accumulation and competition for higher profits, all capitalists
do not succeed equally; the cost of failure is also unequally distributed among
different sectors, regions, and localities. Different sectors and different firms within
the same sector, located in the same or separate localities, have different rates of
profit. These differences arise from certain conditions of capitalist development
which are unevenly distributed across sectors and regions and which can be
distinguished in three major categories: (1) conditions which affect the sphere of
production, that is, the production or extraction of surplus value; (2) conditions
which affect the sphere of circulation or exchange,.that is, the realization of surplus
value; and (3) conditions which affect the reproduction of dominant social relations
and in particular the reproduction of the labor force.
I have already discussed the intervening role of the state and the local state,
particularly in the sphere of circulation and reproduction. These conditions are part
of the so-called 'total capital' available for each individual capitalist, which is to a
large extent 'space-specific' and 'particular to a location'. Some of these conditions
constitute what Harvey (1981) calls a 'spatial-fix', such as workers' housing, urban
and regional infrastructure, social facilities, and other means of collective consumption.
Every individual capitalist enterprise thus tends, through competition and state
intervention, to improve its own 'internal' dynamic in terms of technology, labor
process, restructuring, etc; it also improves its own 'external' dynamic in terms of
these localized conditions, so thatat least temporarilyit enjoys higher than average
social profits. In addition, collectively as a class, capitalists form national and
regional associations and, through the state and local authorities, intervene in issues of
common interest.
Although these fundamental concepts and processes are quite familiar, their
contradictory implications within the geographical setting have seldom been explored.
One reason for this may be that very often radical analysis has narrowly focused on
one aspect of the problem only. I will argue here, however, that such a partial viewpoint mystifies and obscures tendencies and contradictions that permit the production
of surplus value to diverge from its geographical distribution (Harvey, 1983). Such an
approach requires a fresh look at these localized conditions, not as simple attributes
of place, but as 'active moments' in the geographical organization of capitalism.
The improvement of the whole tissue of antagonistic conditions in all sectors and
regions of a social formation is the driving force behind capitalist development and
expansion, and it is achieved through competition and state intervention. Through
these improvements, general conditions of social production across regions and
sectors tend to equalize towards a social average, producing at the same time an
homogeneous space. As Marx (1981) observed in Capital (Volume 3), profits tend
also to approximate the social average; in other words, a tendency towards
equalization of the rates of profit is in operation.
This tendency, however, creates problems for capitalist development. The very
tendency towards profit equalization and spatial homogenization minimizes capitalist
expansion, since no excess profits can be obtained with equal rates of profit in all
sectors and all regions. No more accumulation will be possible, except that necessary

Tho geographical transfer of vnluo

337

for demographic growth, and this itself would be modified in its own turn by the
impact of the severe economic stagnation that would ensue (Emmanuel, 1969).
Furthermore, the equalization tendency threatens the reproduction of capitalist social
relations, which are founded on the unequal distribution of the social product, both
between capitalists and workers and among capitalists themselves.
A very effective counterbalance to the equalization tendency has been a
combination of class strategies, by individual capitalists and the state, towards
differentiation across sectors and regions of the very conditions described earlier,
For example, the introduction by an individual firm of technical innovation could
differentiate it from others and restore its profitability; a managerial strategy to
increase wages in a certain firm or region above the national agreement with the state
creates 'barriers of entry* to other less-powerful firms in the same sector, or pushes
others to cease production; an allocation of public investments to specific regions
increases their competitiveness in attracting private capital vis-iVvis other regions; and
the introduction by the state of a special land-use legislation or the construction of a
new highway system assigns specific and differentiated roles to every territory, so
that a parccllizcd and fragmented regional space is produced (Lcfcbvrc, 1974; Lipietz,
1977; Poulantzas, 1978). These observations help to clarify another tendency,
namely that towards differentiation of the rate of profit.
The organization of space is a very important element in the tendency towards
differentiation. Some spatial differentiation is inevitable in any mode of production;
it is derived, on the one hand, from the simple friction of distance, and, on the other,
from the basic principle of agglomeration versus dispersal in human spatial
organization. These transhistorical spatial characteristics have been used by capital
and the state to produce a disarticulated and fragmented regional space based on the
relative mobility of capital, the relative immobility of labor, and the territoriality of
certain general conditions of social production. As Harvey (1983, page 441) observed:
"The homogeneity towards which the law of value tends contains its own negation in
increasing regional inequalities. All kinds of opportunities then arise for competition
and unequal exchange between regions .... The result is a chaos of confused and
distorted motions towards both homogeneity and regional differentiation".
Taken together within the framework of uneven geographical development, these
contradictory relations can be summarized and focused around the principal contradiction of spatial differentiation and spatial equalization in capitalist development.
This contradiction is specific to the capitalist mode of production and central to
capitalism's spatial problematic. Whether we refer to the internationalization of
capital within a world system, to regional inequalities within a particular social
formation, or to the political economy of urban space, uneven regional development
arises from these two simultaneous and opposing tendencies, and acts back upon them
in terms both of the logic and strategy of capitalist accumulation and of the logic and
strategy of working-class struggle.
The broad significance of the contradiction has been elaborated by a number of
Marxists. Palloix (1975) has been perhaps the most explicit analyst of equalization
and differentiation on an international and regional scale, showing the connection of
the contradiction with Lenin's law of uneven development'. Emmanuel (1969) and
Mandel (1975) emphasize its economic implications, and Lefebvre (1974; 1976) puts
his emphasis on the spatial dimension of the contradiction, especially at the urban
scale. Iipietz (1980) discusses the 'perpetual struggle' between 'inherited' and
'projected' space in regional development. Finally, Poulantzas (1978) identifies the
linked pairs of paradoxical oppositions, such as fragmentation versus homogenization,
division versus unification, and parcellization versus structuring in connection with the
key role of the state.

338

C Hadjimichalis

The combination of differentiation and equalization is not some dialectical sleight


of hand designed to absolve those who have been criticized for leaving unresolved the
question of whether capitalism increases or decreases regional inequalities, and
whether it homogenizes or differentiates in its spatial extension (Soja, 1981).
Capitalism can do both, and can do both simultaneously. But this happens not as
the result of some inner logic of capital, or of some laws of motion of the capitalist
mode of production', but as the result of an intervention by a political agent
producing changes in the character of the dominant social relations of production,
exchange, and consumption (Dulong, 1978; Poulantzas, 1978). This criticism applies
to Harvey's (1983) economistic emphasis in The Limits to Capital, in which politics,
ideology, class struggle, and the state are almost absent from the discussion.
The movement towards equalization or differentiation is not a matter of free choice
by capital and the state. It is the outcome of class struggle between capital and labor
over the production of surplus value, and of competition between capitalists over the
distribution of surplus value. The reproduction of the general social conditions is an
'active moment' within the overall accumulation process, and is bound up with the
perpetual motion in the spatial configuration of capitalist social relations. Thus the
reproduction of these conditions becomes a political necessity via the intervention of
the central state and the local government (Folin, 1981; Lojkine, 1977; Preteceille,
1981). This is why issues such as capital restructuring, regional and urban decline,
and 'the regional crisis' are part, not only of the general crisis of capital, but also of
the crisis of the state in virtually every European capitalist social formation.
6 The geographical transfer of value
It is now possible to return to a discussion of the geographical transfer of value
(GTV) and to 'locate' it within the framework of capitalist social relations and the
contradiction inherent in the equalization-differentiation debate.
GTV can be defined as the tendency or process through which the value produced
for exchange by workers at one locality:
(a) is realized by the capitalists who have employed these workers, but profits have
been reinvested elsewhere; and/or
(b) is at least partially realized by the capitalists who have employed these workers
and is added as excess profits to other capitalists in other localities.
The first case could be referred to as direct and/or derived GTV, whereas the second
could be called indirect and/or originating GTV (Hadjimichalis, 1980; Soja, 1981).
In both cases, however, profits have been added to the accumulation process enjoyed
by other capitalists in other areas.
A number of clarifications are necessary. To begin with, GTV differs from the
autonomous and transfer-of-surplus-development theses because, first, it takes
production and circulation as a dialectical unity; second, it is not an automatic
process, but it is conditional, that is, its operation is dependent on certain conditions
which are analyzed below; third, it is not the only or even the major factor
influencing development, but one among many; and fourth, its relative weight
depends on a concrete time-space conjuncture.
Another important clarification is the definition of 'locality'. 'Local' refers to
the importance of local variations in action, consciousness, and conditions, with a
labor market playing the crucial role (Cooke, 1983; Duncan and Goodwin, 1982).
'Locality' is not a predefined sociospatial unit, but it must result as an effect from
the analysis of local labor market characteristics and boundaries (Kayser, 1970).
Finally, GTV is not the simple geographical component of the sectoral transfer of
value analyzed by Marx. If this were the case, we would end with a contextual view
of abstract space and the argument would be a cyclical one. The peculiarity of GTV

UuMioofjniphiail tmnnfnr of vnlun

339

derives from its connection with concrete space materialised in sociospatial relations
which are particular to a place. This connection with material space is evident in
three important characteristics: the local class structure, the local labor market, and
local general conditions of social production. These three characteristics, differentiated
or equalized among localities, are the preconditions for GTV to occur, and they are
controlled or produced by the central and/or the local state. In the following, I
shall consider how these characteristics could be classified as local* (most of them
are considered as 'national') and how they are related to the concept of GTV.
I begin by noting that historical changes in contemporary capitalist relations have
increased the importance of local class structures (Duncan and Goodwin, 1982;
Urry, 1981). The accelerated derealization of economic relationships has been
followed by an increasing 'poiiticization' of economic activity through conflict
affecting local struggles in class, gender, or ethnic composition. Of major importance
here is the increased role of the state and of large national and multinational
expenditure and employment patterns unevenly distributed amongst various localities.
These changes may serve as a 'material basis' to raise workers' consciousness, but may
also serve to raise territorially based class alliances (Harvey, 1983). Such territorial
class alliances are mainly issue-oriented; they are mobilized either in defence of the
local social reproduction process (for example, to protect jobs and state expenditure)
or to improve it vis-a-vis other localities (for instance, to attract a new plant). The
more territorial class alliances are organised to gain positive agreements with capital
and the state (along with rising productivity), the better the relative position of a
particular locality in the national and international division of labor. Thus, having
been 'eliminated' as an economic structure, the locality reappears with another
meaning, and on a different scale, as the framework of a new form of exploitation
(Damette, 1980).
The connection between labor-market theories and local development has been
widely applied in Italy during the 1960s and 1970s (Arcangeli et al, 1980; Garofoli,
1974; Magniani, 1978), and later in the neo-dualism thesis (Mingione, 1978). It has
also attracted major interest among English-speaking scholars (Cooke, 1983;
Friedman, 1977; Massey and Meegan, 1982; Urry, 1981). The basic idea is that the
development process produces, and in turn reproduces, a spatially diverse division of
labor. Some areas display a concentration of prestigious well-paid jobs for which a
substantial level of qualifications is a prerequisite; others tend to display the inverse
of these qualities. Once established, this spatial division of labor changes over time,
undergoing a permanent dynamic process of recomposition in relation to the conflict
between accumulation imperatives and worker resistance.
The internationalization of capital and the growing intervention of central and
local state create a fragmented local labor market able to provide the necessary
stability and loyalty to corporate decisions (Friedman, 1977; Garofoli, 1983). Since
labor power is produced and reproduced outside the factory, the relationship between
capital and labor becomes one of double-dependence. It also creates a paradox: in
an era of hypermobility and telecommunication, labor markets tend to be more and
more decomposed and fragmented at the local level, while labor is willing less and
less to move outside the locality for jobs (Garofoli, 1983).
Finally, of major local importance are the general conditions of social production,
to which Marx (1973, page 33) alludes in a famous passage in Grundrisse. By
general conditions, I mean those services, infrastructure, and goods produced directly
or indirectly by the central and local state (Folin, 1981; Lojkine, 1977). The
provision of these general conditions is highly uneven over space and is the basis for
the differential attractiveness of various localities to capital and labor. The kind,
quantity, and quality of these general conditions increase the local rate of surplus

340

C Hadjimichalis

value and/or the rate of profit. This is achieved by increasing the productivity of
labor, or by reducing the cost of the reproduction of labor power, or by reducing the
turnover time of capital (O'Connor, 1973). In other words, the state tends to
socialize the cost of production and to lower the cost of circulation (Folin, 1981).
The whole process is contradictory, however, because these conditions are produced
as public expenditures and not as commodities. At the same time, these expenditures
act as a 'counter tendency' to the fall in the rate of profit, thus increasing the
competitiveness of certain localities vis-a-vis others.
Thus far, I have argued that important changes in local class structure, local labor
markets, and general conditions of social production will produce significant
variations among different localities. My focus on these issues served also to emphasize
the unity between production and circulation, and the particular importance of spacetime structures for the realization of surplus value. In the following, I will consider
how such variations may give rise to GTV.
Marx defined the 'realization of surplus value' in terms of the successful movement
of capital through the three phases of circulation: value appears first as money
(when capitalists are acting as buyers); second it appears as labor force (when
capitalists are acting as organizers of production); and, third it appears as a material
commodity (when capitalists are acting as sellers). These transformations are not
taking place at the same time and within the same territory. This means that
realization of surplus value could take place within or outside the area where it has
been produced, and in short or extended periods of time. I have to emphasize that
neither value nor surplus value are created in circulation, because in this process
commodities are merely exchanged, not created. It is in circulation, however, that
the value magnitudes take their money forms: value, the form of money-price; and
surplus value, the form of money-profit (Morishima, 1973).
The sum of profit for individual capitalists located in a particular locality is
calculated at the end of the third movement. It forms a 'localized accumulation',
thus representing the spatially differentiated impulses towards capitalist expansion.
Through the operation of equalization or differentiation, localized accumulation is
dependent on local class structure, the local labor market, and the relative development
of the general conditions of social production. The greater the mass of surplus value
produced, the greater the proportion of surplus value realized locally, as well as in
other regions; and the greater the mass of excess profit, the faster will be the whole
process of capital turnover. Broadly speaking, GTV occurs in direct and indirect ways.
Direct or derived GTV occurs when certain visible actions by social agents (usually,
but not exclusively, outside the donor region) intervene so that part of the surplus
value produced locally is transferred elsewhere. The mediation by these agents
involves a series of actions, which vary historically from direct violence, war, and
plunder to more sophisticated policies such as state taxation policies, price policy,
public transfer payments, multinational profit repatriation, and transfer-pricing.
The common denominator behind all these means of direct GTV is their mediation
through institutions, especially through the state in combination with industrial and
finance capital. In this respect it is important to note the material basis for an
immediate link of derived or direct GTV both to the role of the state and to class
struggle over the production of regional space.
Indirect or originating GTV operates 'indirectly' through the antagonistic capitalist
market. The problem here is associated with the transformation of values into
prices of production, and then to actual prices in the market. This is known as the
'transformation problem', a much-debated and problematic issue in Marxist political
economy (Elson, 1979). It reflects the differences which exist between the value
content of commodities and their relative exchange prices. It should be noted,

Tho Oftoomphleo! tronnfor of vnluo

341

however, that the operation of the capitalist market was never perfect or selfregulated, To some extent, indirect GTV could be located under the same general
concept of direct GTV, especially in connection with the growing economic function
of the state. Thus the distinction between direct and indirect GTV is a methodological one and has no political implications, as I attempt to demonstrate below.
In indirect GTV, the transformation from direct prices to prices of production
does not involve any real change for the system as a whole (Morishima, 1973;
Shaikh, 1980). The total mass of commodities, and the various portions of it going
to each class, remains the same as before. By the same token, so do the sum of
values and the sum of surplus value. All that changes is the manner in which given
production relations are manifested in circulation (Shaikh, 1980), What the
transformation brings about is a different division of the total pool of surplus value
among individual capitalists having their firms in different or in the same regions.
With the direct prices, each capitalist realizes an amount of money-profit equivalent
to the surplus value contained in the commodities being sold. With prices of
production, each regional sector's money-profit is no longer proportional to its
surplus value produced locally; since the sum of values (and hence the total surplus
value produced in the social formation as a whole) is still the same as before, the
above change of form has the effect of redistributing surplus value from one sphere
of production to another, and from one locality to another.
As dc Vroey (1981) and Lipictz (1983) have shown, the prices of all commodities
produced in various sectors and regions of a national market (taken together) must
be equivalent to their collective value, but the price of an individual commodity is
not necessarily equal to its value. The tendency towards equalization of the rate of
profit does not equalize the price of commodities. On the contrary, the average rate
of profit and the market prices permit a sector or firm which operates in a certain
region under more favorable technical, social, and locational conditions to realizeaside from its own surplus valuepart of the nonrealized surplus value of other
sectors and regions. As Marx states (1981, page 829):
"... it is true in fact that the average prices of commodities differ from their value,
thus from the labour realized in them, and the average profit of a particular
capital differs from the surplus value which this capital has extracted from the
labourers employed by it".
And he also states (1969, page 30), describing the transfer of value:
"It is therefore wrong to say that competition among capitalists brings about a
general rate of profit by equalizing the prices of commodities to their values.
On the contrary it does so by converting the values of the commodities into
average prices, in which a part of the surplus value is transferred from one
commodity to another and from one capitalist to another capitalist".
These value transfers could be better understood in terms of circulation profits,
circulation losses, and losses of value (de Vroey, 1981). Profits and losses in circulation
result from the lack of full realization of the norms of exchange. They occur in
different localities when there is a situation of a seller having power, derived from a
local strength (described earlier) in terms of class structure, labor market, and general
conditions of production, to impose a premium on the equilibrium price. The
specific matter of these transfers is that globally they are cancelled out, since the
circulation profits of some are, by definition, the losses of others; their sum amounts
to zero. As Marx (1981, page 168) pointed out:
"... although in selling their commodities the capitalists of the various spheres of
production recover the value of the capital consumed in their production, they
do not secure the surplus value, and consequently the profit, created in their
own sphere by the production of these commodities ....

C Hadjimichalis

... the various capitalists are just so many stock holders in a stock company in
which the shares of profit are uniformly divided per 100, so that profits differ in
the case of the individual capitalists only in accordance with the amount of capital
invested by each".
Similarly, losses of value arise from two sources: lack of sale or devalorization of
the means of production (Harvey, 1983). The first results from mistaken choices
of production and bad management in circulation. The second results from a sudden
drop of value of the means of production. In contrast to losses in circulation, losses
of value always represent waste in the allocation of the social labor of a commodity
system. In this case, GTV does not occur; it is the 'price' paid for the way social
cohesion is formed in a particular society.
Thus the total mass of profit available for accumulation in a given locality at a
certain time will consist of two positive and two negative components: first, profit
stemming from surplus value extracted and realized locally or elsewhere, plus interclass profit or circulation to the benefit of capital; second, profits will be eliminated
as a result of direct and indirect GTV, and/or because of losses of value. These
joint effects form the basis for an analysis of individual sectoral and geographical
differentials in profitability, the motive for capitalist competition and expansion;
individual capitalists struggle to sell at or above the social average, while producing
at a local cost which must be lower than the social average.
7 Concluding comment
These observations clearly deserve further elucidation and interpretation. The main
point to be made, however, is twofold. First, contradictory tendencies towards
equalization and differentiation operate throughout the hierarchical structure of
uneven geographical development, affecting the reproduction of dominant social
relations at multiple scales. This in turn provides the material basis for GTV to
occur under certain conditions, shaped by potentially conflicting strategies of
equalization and differentiation, preservation and destruction, fragmentation and
homogenization. Second, GTV is taking place in the sphere of circulation and
exchange, but its magnitude and direction (positive or negative) is determined in the
sphere of production. If GTV exists, it is not an automatic process, an outcome of
some internal law of capital accumulation; it requires the direct and/or indirect
intervention of a political agent. This is different from the sectoral transfer of value,
which is supposed to act through imperfect competition and the capitalist market.
Thus if GTV is influencing uneven geographical development, it is expressed
primarily as the outcome of a spatially differentiated accumulation process in which
the development of some regions is always at the expense of others. What this
means in part is that GTV is the result of particular historical processes, rather than
a specific process in itself. This should not be interpreted, however, to suggest that
GTV (as an 'outcome' of uneven capitalist development) can be separated from the
dynamic of capitalist development as a 'process'. Clearly the aim was to show how
uneven geographical development both shapes and is shaped by GTV.
To a significant degree, the. subject of GTV has only recently been revealed as
part of a much broader process of demystifying the spatiality of capitalism. Just as
other Marxists used the commodity form and its demystification to unveil the inner
workings of capital in general, so too it may be possible to use an interpretation of
uneven geographical development based on GTV both to comprehend and to
transform capitalism.

Tho cjoonrophicnl irnmfor of vnluo

343

Acknowledgements, I am grateful to all who made helpful comments on various occasions,


especially Dina Vafou, Ed Soja, Alain Lipietz, Peter Maskcll, Ray Hudson, Viggo Plum, and Honrlk
Toft Jensen, I also found the comments of Michael Dear and two anonymous referees very
constructive. None of these individuals are responsible for the final product.
References
Alvater E, 1973, "Notes on some problems of state intcrvcntionisni" Kapitalistate issue 1/2,
pp 18-31
Amin S, 1978 Ww Law of Value and Historical Materialism (Monthly Review Press, New York)
Arcangcli F, Bozzaga C, Groglio S, 1980, "Patterns of peripheral development in Italian regions,
1964-77'* paper presented to the 19th European Congress of the Regional Science Association,
London; copy available from C Hadjimichalis
Bajcc J, 1983, "Regional disparities in Yugoslavia*' in Tltc Crises of the European Regions Eds
D Seers, K Ostrtim (Macmillan, London) pp 47-61
Baran P, Swcezy P, 1970 Monopoly Capital (Penguin Books, Harmondsworth, Middx)
Bauer 0, 1924 Die Nationalitatenfragcn und die Sozialdemokratie (Vienna)
Boeeara P, 1971 Traite dfEconomic Marxiste: Le Capitalisme Monopollste de VEtat (Editions
Soelalcs, Paris)
Bukharin N, 1973 Imperialism and World Economy (Monthly Review Press, New York)
Carney J, Hudson J, Ivc G, Lewis J, 1975, "Regional underdevelopment in late capitalism: a study
of the North East of England" in London Papers in Regional Science 6: Theory and Practice
in Regional Science Ed. I Masscr (Pion, London) pp 11-29
Chcrpakov V, 1969 State Monopoly Capitalism (Progress Publishers, Moscow)
Cooke P, 1983 Theories of Planning and Spatial Development (Hutchinson, London)
Damcttc F, 1980, "The regional framework of monopoly exploitation: new trends*' in Regions in
Oisis Eds J Carney, R Hudson, J Lewis (Croom Helm, Bcckenham, Kent) pp 76-91
Dear M, Clark G L, 1981, "Dimensions of local state autonomy" Environment and Planning A 13
1277-1294
De Janvry A, 1981 77i<? Agrarian Question and Reformism in Latin America (The Johns Hopkins
University Press, Baltimore, MD)
De Vrocy M, 1981, "Value, production and exchange" in The Value Controversy (Verso, London)
pp 173-201
Dos Santos T, 1970, "The structure of dependence" American Economic Review 60 231-236
Dulong R, 1976, "La crise du raport etat-societe locale a traverse du politique regionale" in l a
Crise de VEtat Ed. N Poulantzas (PUF, Paris) pp 68-95
Dulong R, 1978 Les Regions, VEtat et la Societe Locale (PUF, Paris)
Duncan S S, Goodwin M, 1982, "The local state and restructuring social relations" International
Journal of Urban and Regional Research 6 157-185
Elson D (Ed.), 1979 Value: Tfie Representation of Labour in Capitalism (CSE Books, London)
Emmanuel A, 1969 VEchange Inegal (Maspero, Paris)
Ferrao J, 1982, "Regional variations in rates of profit in Portuguese industry" paper presented at
the Conference on National and Regional Development in the Mediterranean Basin, Durham;
copy available from the Department of Geography, University of Durham, Durham DH1 3HP,
England
Folin M, 1981, "The production of the general conditions of social production and the role of the
state" in Gty, Class and Capital Eds M Harloe, E Lebas (Edward Arnold, London) pp 51-60
Frank A G, 1969 Capitalism and Underdevelopment in Latin America (Modern Reader, New York)
Friedman A L, 1977 Industry and Labor (Macmillan, London)
Garofoli J, 1974, "Regional inequality and the labor market" paper presented at the Reunion des
Chercheurs Europeens sur la Question Regionale, Paris; copy available from J Garofoli, Instituto
di Scienze Economiche, Universita di Pavia, Pa via, Italy
Garofoli J, 1983, "Uneven regional development and industrial restructuring: the Italian pattern
in the 1970s" paper presented to the 1st International Seminar on European Urban and Regional
Problems, Naxos, Greece; copy available from J Garofoli, Instituto di Scienze Economiche,
Universita di Pavia, Pavia, Italy
Glucksmann G B, 1979, "The state, transition and passive revolution" in Gramsci and Marxist
Theory Ed. C Mouffe (Routledge and Kegan Paul, Henley-on-Thames, Oxon) pp 207-236
Gramsci A, 1971 Selections from the Prison Notebooks edited by Q Hoare, C N Smith (International, New York)
Gramsci A, 1973 La Construzione del Partito Comunista (Riuniti, Roma)
Gramsci A, 1975 II Materialismo Storico e la Filosofia di Benedetto Crose (Riuniti, Roma)

344

C Hadjimichalis

Hadjimichalis C, 1980 The Geographical Transfer of Value: A Comparative Analysis of Regional


Development in Southern Europe PhD thesis, Graduate School of Architecture and Planning,
University of California at Los Angeles, Los Angeles, CA 90024, USA
Hadjimichalis C, forthcoming Uneven Development and Regionalism: State, Territory and Class in
Southern Europe (Croom Helm, Beckenham, Kent)
Harvey D, 1975, "The geography of capitalist accumulation: a reconstruction of the Marxist
theory" Antipode 7 9-21
Harvey D, 1981, "The space-economy of capitalist production: a Marxist interpretation" paper
presented at the Conference on New Perspectives on the Urban Political Economy, London;
copy available from D Harvey, Department of Geography, The Johns Hopkins University,
Baltimore, MD 21218, USA
Harvey D, 1983 The Limits to Capital (Basil Blackwell, Oxford)
Himmelweit S, Mohun S, 1978, "The anomalies of capital" Capital and Class issue 6, pp 67-105
Hirsch J, 1981, "The apparatus of the State, the reproduction of capital and urban conflicts" in
Urbanization and Urban Planning in Capitalist Societies Eds M Dear, A J Scott (Methuen,
Andover, Hants) pp 593-607
Hodgson G, 1981, "Critique of Wright: labour and profits" in The Value Controversy (Verso,
London) pp 75-99
Kayser B, 1970 Manpower Movements and Labour Markets (Organisation for Economic Cooperation
and Development, Paris)
Kuusinen O, Retrof J, Kanisky O, 1973 Fundamentals of Marxism-Leninism (Foreign Languages
Press, Moscow)
Laclau E, 1977 Politics and Ideology in Marxist Theory (Verso, London)
Laclau E, Mouffe C, 1981, "Socialist strategy: where next?" Marxism Today IS 25-32
Lapple D, van Hoogstraten P, 1980, "Remarks on the spatial structure of capitalist development:
the case of the Netherlands" in Regions in Crisis Eds J Carney, R Hudson, J Lewis (Croom
Helm, Beckenham, Kent) pp 117-166
Lefebvre H, 1974 La Production de VEspace (Anthropos, Paris)
Lefebvre H, 1976 The Survival of Capitalism (Allison and Busby, London)
Lenin V I, 1973 Imperialism: The Highest Stage of Capitalism (Progress Publishers, Moscow)
Liossatos P, 1979, "Unequal exchange and regional disparities" paper presented to the Regional
Science Association Conference, Los Angeles; copy available from C Hadjimichalis
Lipietz A, 1977 Le Capital et son Espace (Maspero, Paris)
Iipietz A, 1980, "The structuration of space, the problem of land and spatial policy" in Regions
in Crisis Eds J Carney, R Hudson, J Lewis (Croom Helm, Beckenham, Kent) pp 60-73
Lipietz A, 1981, "The so-called transformation problem revised" Journal of Economic Theory 26
59-88
Lipietz A, 1983, "La debat sur la valeur: bilan partiel et perspectives partiales" research paper
8326, Centre d'Etudes Prospectives d'Economie Mathematique Appliquees a la Planification,
75013 Paris, France
Lojkine J, 1977 Le Marxisme, VEtat et la Question Urbaine (PUF, Paris)
Magniani A, 1978, "Ristrutturazione e diffusione territorale del ciclo produttivo: formazione della
'Fabrica Diffusa' in Italia" paper presented to the 1st Seminario Internationale del Workshop
Area Mediterranea, Milano; copy available from A Magniani, Facolta di Architettura,
Politechnico de Milano, Milano, Italy
Mandel E, 1975 Late Capitalism (New Left Books, London)
Markusen A, 1983, "Profit cycles, oligopoly and regional transformation" WP-397, Institute of
Urban and Regional Development, Berkeley, CA 94720, USA
Marx K, 1969 Theories of Surplus Value (Lawrence and Wishart, London)
Marx K, 1973 Grundrisse (Penguin Books, Harmondsworth, Middx)
Marx K, 1976 Capital volume 1 (Penguin Books, Harmondsworth, Middx)
Marx K, 1981 Capital volume 3 (Penguin Books, Harmondsworth, Middx)
Massey D, 1978, "Regionalism: some current issues" Capital and Class issue 6, pp 106-125
Massey D, Meegan R, 1982 The Anatomy of Job Loss (Methuen, Andover, Hants)
Miliband R, 1974 The State in Capitalist Society (Quartet Books, London)
Mingione E, 1978, "Capitalism, crisis, neo-dualism and marginalization" International Journal of
Urban and Regional Research 2 213-221
Morishima M, 1973 Marx's Economics: A Dual Theory of Value and Growth (Cambridge University
Press, Cambridge)
O'Connor J, 1973 The Fiscal Crisis of the State (St Martin's Press, New York)

Tho geographical transfer of vnluo

346

Offe C, 1974, ''Structural problems of the capitalist state" in German Political Studies. Volume I
Gel, K von Beume (Sage, London) pp 215-236
I^iggi L, 1979, "Gramsefs general theory of Marxism** in Gramsci ami Marxist Theory Ed.
C Mouffc (Routledge and Kcgan Paul, Henley-on-Thames, Oxen) pp 113-167
I^illolx Cf 1975 L'lnternationatimtion du Capital (Masp&o, Paris)
Pcrrota C, 1981, "On Marxist theories of unequal exchange'* DP-75, Development Studies,
University of East Anglia, Norwich NR4 7TJ, England
PouIaiUzas N (Ed.). 1976 La Crlso de VEtat (PUP, Paris)
Poulantzas N, 1978 State, Power, Socialism (Verso, London)
Poulantzas Nf 1979, "The crisis of Marxism" interview given to TA NBA, 12 February, page 4
and 13 February, page 5
Preteceille E, 1981, "Collective consumption, the state and the crisis of capitalist society" in
City, Class and Capital Eds M Harloc, E Lcbas (Edward Arnold, London) pp 1-16
Scott A J, 1980 The Urban Land Nexus and the State (Pion, London)
Shaikh A, 1980, "Foreign trade and the law of value" Science and Society 12 281-302
Shaikh A, 1981, "The poverty of algebra" in 77te Value Controversy (Verso, London) pp 266-300
Soja E, 1980, "The socio-spatial dialectic" Annals of the American Association of Geographers
70 207-225
Soja E, 1981, "A materialist interpretation of spatiality" paper presented at the Workshop on the
Geographical Transfer of Value, Canberra; copy available from E Soja, Graduate School of
Architecture and Urban Planning, 405 Hilgard Avenue, Los Angeles, CA 90024, USA
Soja E, 1983, "Territorial idealism and the political economy of regional development" City and
Region issue 6, pp 55-73
Sraffa P, I960 Production of Commodities by Means of Commodities (Cambridge University Press,
Cambridge, MA)
Steedman 1, 1977 Marx after Sraffa (New Left Books, London)
Toft Jensen H, 1982, "The role of the state in regional development, planning, and implementation:
the case of Denmark" in London Papers in Regional Science 11: Regional Planning in Europe
Eds R Hudson, J R Lewis (Pion, London) pp 127-147
Urry J, 1981, "Localities, regions and social class" International Journal of Urban and Regional
Research 5 455-473
Walker R, 1978, "Two sources of uneven development under advanced capitalism: spatial
differentiation and capital mobility" The Review of Radical Political Economics 10 28-37
Webber M J, 1982, "Agglomeration and the regional question" Antipode 14 1-11
Wright E O, 1978 Class, Crisis and the State (Verso, London)
Wright E O, 1981, "The value controversy and social research" in The Value Controversy (Verso,
London) pp 36-74

You might also like