You are on page 1of 10

Agric Hum Values (2009) 26:335344

DOI 10.1007/s10460-009-9225-6

Discussion: moving food regimes forward: reflections


on symposium essays
Harriet Friedmann

Received: 22 June 2009 / Accepted: 22 June 2009 / Published online: 6 August 2009
 Springer Science+Business Media B.V. 2009

Abstract All authors in this symposium use a food ideological or discursive aspects of an operative regime,
regime perspective to ask questions about the present that is, one whose historical tensions are, as McMichael puts
whichas these articles demonstratehave several pos- it, stabilized. This narrow definition can guide the inquiry:
sible answers. History suggests a time perspective of regime or no regime (yet)? To address the question of
2540 year cycles so fara food regime 18701914, an transition, which can be defined as a period of unresolved
experimental and chaotic era 19141947, and a food experimentation and contestation, we can ask whether or
regime 19471973. It has been less than 40 years since not there exists a sufficiently stable constellation of agri-
1973, when food regime analysts agree that a contested and food relationships so that states, individuals, corporations,
experimental period began. There is no consensus on social movements and other actors can predict the outcome
whether it has already ended or how it might issue into a of actions. Relatedly, do actors see the present repertoire of
new food regime. The conversation is more fruitful than actions and consequences as more or less naturala key
the conclusions. I intend these comments as an invitation to element of legitimacy (Campbell this issue)?
join in. If a food regime can be said to exist, the next step is
naming it. This brings into play the second definition of
Keywords Food regimes  International financial food regimes. The classical definition of food regimes
system  Hegemonic transition  Actor network theory  includes constellations of class relations, geographical
Regulation  Social change specialization, and inter-state power (Friedmann 1993).
Friedmann and McMichael (1989, p. 95) linked interna-
tional relations of food production and consumption to
Introduction periods of capitalist accumulation. This wrote into the
world-systems perspectivein which capitalism begins
Thinking about food regime transition and/or emergence is with colonial expansion in 1500a focus on the shorter
partly empirical, partly definitional. I would like to play and more recent periods defined by the French Regulation
with two definitions. First, it may help to bring in a precise School. It shifted Regulation School focus from national
and limited definition of international regimes used in the states to the system of states, and from industry to agri-
International Organization literature: a specific set of (often culture. It added to early world-systems theory empirical
implicit) relationships, norms, institutions, and rules around mappings of class relations and geographical specializa-
which the expectations of all relevant actors converge tions related to historically specific commodity com-
(Krasner 1983). This emphasizes the implicitly shared plexes.1 Which relations are pivots of the stabilized
tensions which allow for predictable responses? Burch and
Lawrence and McMichael say yes to a new food regime
H. Friedmann (&)
Department of Sociology and Centre for International Studies,
1
University of Toronto, 1 Devonshire Place, Toronto, ON M5S Commodity chain analysis, in turn, benefited from attention to
3K7, Canada wider patterns of capital accumulation and inter-state power brought
e-mail: harriet.friedmann@utoronto.ca by food regimes (Collins 2005).

123
336 H. Friedmann

and offer different names to key relationships. Power is A financialized food regime?
stabilized (to different degrees) around either a financial or
a corporate pivot. Burch and Lawrence lay out an elegant, well supported
If there is not an identifiable set of stabilized tensions, argument for a financialized food regime within a larger
the food regime optic suggests another transitional per- tendency towards financialization of the whole economy.
iodor perhaps the end of regime cycles. Transitional eras They follow a thread of shifting power from supermarkets in
are full of multiple possibilities. Conflicts name newly the 1990s, which they pioneered in identifying and
delegitimizedi.e. previously naturalizedaspects of the explaining (Burch and Lawrence 2007), to financial enter-
old food regime and offer competing frames for resolving prises in the 2000s, which they similarly lead in identifying
them (Friedmann 2005a). Pritchard, Campbell, and Dixon, and explaining. Although the financial crisis unleashed in
each in a distinct way, see the outcome as still open. 2008 brought hedge funds and private equity into public
I see elective affinities in these papers: (1) between vocabularies, these institutions are too little understood.
political economy and the identification (or negation) of a Supermarkets, they show, have been reorganized via private
new food regime, and (2) between nature-centered aspects, equity takeovers, so that old uncapitalized property has
namely ecology and health, and a continuing play of ele- become real estate, and new profit centers arise by offering
ments potentially constellating a new regime. So I play financial services. This is required reading for anyone
with a double focus on naming the transitions and social- interested in power and property in the food system.
natural aspects of agri-food relations. Burch and Lawrences case for a power shift towards
financial institutions draws on a specific thread of agri-food
history. As I read it, Burch and Lawrences argument takes
Political economy of food regimes: remembering up the story of capitalist power concerning industrialization
hegemony of food and agriculture, which had already gone far in
subordinating food and farming to the larger capitalist
Regime means regulation: there exist rules which ana- economy in so-called developed economies. After World
lysts can infer through consistent behaviors of relevant War II, in the US-centered food regime, agriculture and
actors: states, enterprises, corporations, social movements, food industries (as they came to be called) became major
consumers, and scientists. Rules in this sense are some- drivers of the then leading sectors (in technological inno-
times hard to pin down, but the effort is worth it. In food vation and profit), machinery and chemicals. Far more than
regime analysis, they relate both to state regulation, automobiles and household chemicals, an industrializing
sometimes indirect, and to hegemony. The Gramscian agri-food sector rescued sectors faced with the sudden end
definition of hegemony adapted by Arrighi (1994) includes of wartime government purchases of tanks and nitrogen
much more than monetary (and military) dominance of one (for weapons) by demanding tractors, combines, composite
state within a historically specific system of states. Still, animal feeds, antibiotics, industrial fertilizers, industrial
money is a crucial mechanism of dominanceand of the pesticides, and the rest. However, machinery, chemical,
transfer of wealth from a falling hegemon to emerging and agri-food sectors were not integrated at the level of
powers. Thus, the food aid pivotal to the (capitalist) food ownership or corporate organization. Downstream, farmers
regime of 19471973 (and for foreign aid as a whole) was became suppliers of raw materials to giant food manufac-
a novel mechanism dependent on specific institutions of the turers (supermarkets were still infants). The imbalance in
Bretton Woods monetary system2; the demise of that sys- power between even the largest farmers and giant agri-
tem meant that aid, including food aid, has worked dif- cultural input and food manufacturing corporations created
ferently ever since.3 I think that hegemony, particularly the famous cost-price squeeze. This encouraged ever
monetary institutions, are a crucial missing piece of the larger and more industrial farms, which in turn demanded
political economy contributions, and could enhance their more machines and chemicals.
insights. Then in the 1980s and 1990s a shift in leading tech-
nologies towards genetics (combined with information
2 technologies) led to a reconfiguration of corporate organi-
I cannot include the Cold War, the Detente of 197374 and the
collapse of the Soviet bloc in these brief comments. I note, however, zation and a new importance of agriculture and food as a
that they were crucial to the rise and demise of the US-centered food direct source of profit. Parallel with the new constellation
regime (Friedmann 1993), and wonder how important was the 1990s of Life Sciences, through mergers and acquisitions,
collapse to the fate of the WTO, including the AoA. This is a research
agriculture and food industries became tightly connected
that should be done.
3 with chemical, pharmaceutical, and seed industries. Hor-
A strength of food regime analysis is to identify when meanings of
apparently continuous institutions and behaviors change (Dixon this mones and antibiotics in livestock industries, and geneti-
issue). cally engineered seeds in maize and soy subsectors, have

123
Discussion: moving food regimes forward 337

deepened the technical and corporate integration of agri- Food and agriculture are superb lenses into tensions in
culture and food into the larger capitalist economy (Kuyek the larger political economy because they express the
2007). Indeed, the biological basis of food and farming contradictory commodification of the human (physiologi-
made it an obvious site for application of leading genetic cal) and natural (land) foundations of society (Polanyi
technologies, as Goodman et al. (1987) first argued in 1944). In past writing, McMichael (2004) brilliantly
From Farming to Biotechnology. showed how the development project, which focused
But power and property are not sufficient for a food exclusively on industrialization and consumption of
regime analysis. Are tensions stabilized? What institutions industrial commodities, pushed agriculture to the margins
provide the pivot and give meaning to a stable constellation of theory and policyexcept where it mimicked industry.
of relationships? For instance, is there a counterpart in a This was a crucial flaw, as most institutionsgovern-
financialized food regime to food aid as a pivot of the mental, intergovernmental, scientific, corporateare
194773 food regime? Legitimacy of food aid depended on poorly equipped at best to deal with the cascading prob-
both of the following: (1) convergent interests and expec- lems associated with agri-food industrialization.
tations among diverse and highly unequal actors, including At the same time, the development project expressed a
US farm commodity groups and legislators, Third World state-centered era, and therefore the protection phase of
governments, grain trading corporations, consumers who the cycles Polanyi identified between free markets and
benefited from falling grain and meat prices; and (2) an protection. Agriculture, while marginal in policy focus,
ideological framework that defined these as humanitarian, was nonetheless the most state-centered sector on a world
developmental, or anything but a trade relation, even scale (Friedmann 1993). Thus when the globalization
though the scale of food aid shipments dominated world project replaced the development project to usher in a new
price formation for three decades (Friedmann 1982). By the phase of free markets, agriculture had a special impor-
1980s subsidized exports are universally seen as a bad tance, and its integration into international trade agree-
trade practice (with regime crisis, aid came to be done ments was a key concern in creating the WTO (McMichael
differently), and continuing to do it is not legitimate. 2004). Despite increasing cracks in consensus about
Second, I want to emphasize the missing institutional industrial agriculture, and despite growing experiments in
foundations of postwar concessionary foreign aidthe role alternatives, major institutions inertially move towards
of the dollar in the Bretton Woods monetary system. more of the samemonocultures of a radically declining
Although Burch and Lawrence minimize the effects of the set of cultivars and livestock, which are raw materials for
recent and so far enduring financial crash, it is not obvious food (and fuel) manufacturing. It follows that a corporate
that the processes they carefully describe can endure. These food regime launched in the 1980s and 1990s has met
practices seem likely to exacerbate the volatility of food organized transnational resistance, notably by farmers, but
markets. For instance, can delayed payments to suppliers also by environmentalists and consumers.
really be a stable source of profit for supermarkets? This But does the food regimes approach add value, as it
instance of financialization is predatory; it threatens the were, to a Polanyian interpretation? While Polanyi made
goose that lays the golden eggs, and hardly suggests sta- much of the 19th century monetary system underpinning
bilization of tensions along supply chains. Can enforce- British hegemony (the gold standard), he did not include
ment of ever shorter investment horizons by hyper-mobile hegemonic powerand declinein his theoretical con-
finance go on indefinitely? If these continue to destabilize clusions. From a food regimes perspective, British hege-
farms and other suppliers, and to sacrifice the interests of mony was enacted through an imperial economy in which
politically mobilized ethical and consumer movements, can people, plants and animals were transplanted to create
such a constellation of agri-food investments stabilize? neo-Europes in place of indigenous human (agri)cultures
(Crosby 1986). The gold standard operated within the
British Empire and the larger world system as a mechanism
A corporate food regime? for European settlers, cultivars, livestock and farming
techniques to colonize specialized grain export regions. It
McMichael makes greatly expanded claims for the food was the farm politics in those regions that, after three
regime approach. He uses the metaphor of pivot not for decades of world wars and depression, became the foun-
an element of a food regime, but for food regimes as an dation for a very different food regime in the late 20th
element in capitalist history. Extending the retrospective century (McMichael 1984; Friedmann 2005a). Monetary
reinterpretation of global history through an agri-food lens politics were crucial to the transitional period, and a dollar
(Friedmann and McMichael 1989) into the future, he (rather than gold) standard was crucial to the US regime.
interprets integration with new sectors, such as energy, as Where does international money fit into McMichaels
defining the changing shape of capitalism. account?

123
338 H. Friedmann

Hegemonic crisis and monetary crisis central bank whose main role would be to regulate an
emergent international currency, invented at the time and
If the international monetary system is not stabilized, can called Special Drawing Rights (SDR). An international
there be any food regime? The early 1970s crisis of the currency might have underpinned parallel proposals to
dollar (and the end of Bretton Woods) coincided with the create publicly managed international food stocks. All
OPEC oil cartel and the first food crisis. Comparison with these plans, though the alliances of the time seemed in their
that period may clarify the present. Energy and food, favor, were trumped by what came to be called neoliber-
McMichael shows, are ever more deeply entwined after alism or the Washington Consensus, or the Globalization
decades of making fossil fuels the material foundation of Project.
industrial agriculture. Burch and Lawrence show that The project to turn all this around via private trade and
finance and food are much more complexly entangled now finance emerged over the 1980s. A (very differently)
than in a food regime with government credit to farmers reformed IMF became its leading agent. It forced an end to
and industrial food markets bounded by nationally man- the state-centered, mercantile institutions of the food
aged currencies. The triple links among finance, energy, regime centered on the US, but only as applied to the
and food depend on money, and money is increasingly and indebted Third World.4 Third World states had borrowed
dangerously unstable. It is most directly connected to inter- from private banks to continue to import expensive oil and
state power, that is, hegemonic conflicts which remain food, and within a decade verged on insolvency. Rather
unresolved. than let the banks take the hit for bad loans (sound famil-
By 1973, Third World states had become dependent on iar?), the IMF negotiated longer payment schedules coun-
cheap energy and food imports to support industrialization try by country, and imposed a set of conditionalities
efforts. The Bretton Woods monetary system was the under the new rubric of structural adjustment. Thus the
foundation for national regulation of food and agriculture, IMF became an instrument of debt collection on behalf of
both domestic and export, in all countries, though these Northern banks; the dollar remained the world currency
took different forms in the US, secondary grain exporters, without rules, and the US retained effective veto power via
and the Third World (which shifted from exporters to IMF rules. As a result, Third World countries on the whole
importers under the regime). Typical institutions of the shifted from national agri-food policies (including export
period included marketing boards, and domestic food and management) towards corporate-dominated exports (of
farm subsidies. The relative protection of national planning non-traditional commodities such as counter-seasonal
worked through currencies which were inconvertible. Third fruits, vegetables, and flowers, and of fish) and deepened
World governments typically kept currencies overvalued their dependence on grain imports.5 The US ignored with
in order to make internal commerce more attractive and impunity IMF criticism of its own fiscal and trade deficits;
thus set up virtuous cycles of development within the although farm and export subsidies by both the US and
national economy. Europe came to be widely criticized, they were not subject
When the US unilaterally ended its key role in Bretton to IMF or other international discipline. This is what
Woods by removing the fixed relation between the dollar McMichael calls the corporate food regime. It is what both
and gold, nothing was predictable any more. Something of us have noted changed the focus of food security from
had to change. The dynamics of the early 1970s initially hunger to trade (McMichael 2004; Friedmann 2004).
promised a very different change from the one that unfol- So what is the situation today? Although the Bretton
ded with regard to money, food, and more. The OPEC Woods system ended at the same time as the last food
cartel inspired imitation by rising Third World states. Why regime, nothing has replaced the dollar as international
couldnt all agricultural and mineral exports lead to similar currency. Yet the dollar does not function as it did under
shifts in wealth? These cartels were expected to be sup- Bretton Woods. Instead, the US is able to run deficits in its
ported by enhanced international public stocks, especially government account and in trade supported by the default
of food, and by inter-governmental economic regulation,
including an international currency (Brandt 1980). 4
Which came to be called The South, as Cold War tensions (US and
This project, now almost banished from memory, rep-
allies = First World; Soviet and allies = Second World) gave way to
resented an alliance of Third World states, whose power a richpoor divide. This was a project of the non-aligned countries
was waxing in the still respected United Nations, and social wishing to distance themselves from the dominant Cold War powers
democratic parties and movements, whose power was and forge alliances for shifting power and wealth towards former
colonies which came to be underdeveloped in the postcolonial
waxing in the North, especially Western Europe. It was
world.
intended to correct imbalances in international wealth and 5
Key exceptions, notably India, reflected the contradictory tendency
power (Brandt 1980). It might have stabilized currencies. towards import substitution via industrialization of agriculture known
One plan was to make the IMF a sort of international as the Green Revolution.

123
Discussion: moving food regimes forward 339

position of the dollar as reserve currency. Not only can unraveling food regime, and new elements which became
other countries not do this, but the richer of those countries salient to agri-food politics only after the demise of the old
are financing the US involuntarily for lack of alternatives to food regime. The creation of the WTO, including an
the dollar. This is not stable. Agreement on Agriculture (AoA), was an attempt to extend
Todays financial crisis is also a dollar crisis, deeper the project of the GATT, which was created in 1947 with
now than in the 1970s. US trade (and fiscal) deficits have an explicit exclusion of agriculture from its mandate. It was
been made possible by the holding of reserves by other an old element hanging over, along with mercantile trade,
countries in dollars. The dollar expresses US hegemony, farm, and price policies. By the 1980s, however, the crisis
but trade and fiscal deficits express declining hegemony. of the mercantile practices of the food regime could not be
For Britain after 1914 and earlier hegemonic declines, the ignoredcompetitive export subsidies threatened trade
rise of new currencies (and many related institutions) has wars between powerful states (US and EU). This mattered
so far been affected by wars and depressions (Arrighi and greatly because agriculture and food had become key profit
Silver 1999). Rising states (aka emerging economies) are sectors, with dynamic genetic technologies and deep links
today proposing a new financial architecture, beginning to pharmaceuticals. The AoA was an attempt to bring the
with IMF reforms and increased use of SDRs as an inter- mercantile rules of agri-food into line with liberal rules for
national reserve currency. The IMF now has a legacy of manufacturing.6
stigma (from those forced to accept harsh and counter- Pritchard finds that the World Trade Organization,
productive conditions for credit) and disrespect (by those which some have interpreted as the founding institution of
powerful enough to ignore its criticisms), so that its funds a corporate food regime, was stalemated within a few years
have remained unborrowed in recent years (its major bor- of its establishment. Created in 1995, its setbacks began in
rowers, except Pakistan and Iceland, are former Soviet bloc Seattle in 1999, and by Cancun in 2003 the crucially
nations) (Economist 2009). important AoA was clearly at the heart of its demise. The
But reform is difficult also because the US resists fanfare attending its birth has faltered. The AoA was
changes which would subject it to the same restrictions that agreed only with many blanks to be filled in later, and
Asian states faced in the 199798 financial crisis. China, many exceptions which have undermined its legitimacy.
for instance, proposes an international currency as a Ultimately, the selective application of agreed AoA rules to
negotiated move to recognize that multiple economic the South stalled the whole WTO.
powers exist in place of one hegemon. With trade at its I would extend Pritchards analysis, like the others, by
lowest level in 27 years (Economist 2009), the brave pro- bringing in hegemony. Like McMichael, he emphasizes
nouncements of the G20 express minimal compromise (e.g. NorthSouth conflict at the expense of hegemonic rivalries,
more SDRs) and little consensus between rising and which includes the European Union when it created a
declining powers about the future of international curren- continental currency in the 1990s, the Euro. Yet the trade
cies and finance. As in agri-food, the US cannot have its and subsidy conflicts among the US, Europe, and Japan
way against other powers, but it can veto change and thus (lets call these old rivals still in play) led the three
borrow time in which it forces holders of dollars to sub- powers to agree in 1986 to finally bring agriculture into
sidize its debt. Instability will continue as long as no new international trade agreements, which would formally have
currency (or basket) is adopted which corresponds to the changed moribund food regime rules. These conflicts were
new reality. never resolved. The North closed ranks against a rising
Financialization is a typical feature of the last phase of South (led by India, China and Brazilnew rivals) angry
hegemony. According to Arrighi (1994), it is precisely at the Norths hypocritical refusal to abide by the same
financialization that allows capital to move from the agri-food rules imposed on them. Yet their own conflicts
declining hegemon to one or more rising contenders. were multiplying, as safety issues (hormone beef, GMOs)
Financialization underpinned movements of industry from overtook trade and subsidy battles. Resolution came behind
North to South, and helped dollars flow from the US into the scenes: WTO dispute tribunals consistently supported
factories in China, India, Indonesia, Brazil, and so on. US (and other) challenges to domestically popular Euro-
Financialization, however, does not stabilize anything. pean regulations; the European Union (EU) responded
Military power does not move between states in the same with subterfuges of various kinds to mollify citizens;
way. The mismatch is dangerous. one of these was to accept that the WTO (and Codex

Failed transition? 6
The food regime interpretation of the mercantile specifics of agri-
food is denied by the blanket criticisms of political economy
Pritchards essay exemplifies a strength of food regimes: he approaches by Goodman and Watts (1995, 1997), who see all as
distinguishes between old elements hung over from the imitating industrial sectors.

123
340 H. Friedmann

Alimentarius, the UN standards body) would set minimum strong account of the shifting roles of chemistry and
standards; the private sector, led by supermarkets, would genetics, with attendant technologies, hopes and anxieties;
offer to consumers what governments were prevented of emergence, consolidation and multiple crises of indus-
from offering to citizens. In May 2009, the EU finally trialization and corporate organization; of loss and efforts
agreed to end its expensive prohibition against hormone to recover vernacular and contextually specific knowledge
beef imports (Halliday 2009) and a new US administration of farming and cuisines; of class implications of changing
appears quietly to be dropping retaliatory measures. farming and food systems; and most of all, of the link
If Pritchard extends his analysis to include these rival- between loss of public faith in scientific expertise and
ries, then it may turn out that some institutions of the WTO contention over possible futures. Most compelling, Dixon
are indeed important to the (continuing) conflict over a new and Campbell show how continuing politics of transition
food regime. For instance, Campbell and McMichael see are inflected by multiple, cross-cutting material and ideo-
that international food standards have provided the foun- logical contradictions.
dations for transnational supply chains; moreover, the
private organization of these chains was the default when Campbells feedback criterion for assessing contending
powerful states, notably the European Union, could not regimes
achieve politically demanded standards for livestock and
GM crops (Friedmann 2005a). Similarly, WTO intellectual Campbell argues that two food regimes are in contention,
property rules underpin the move of agri-food corporations each serving two incipiently global classes of consumers:
into spaces occupied by small farmers (Tansey and Rajotte quality foods, fully traceable both technically and
2008; McIntyre et al. 2009). A conflict of principles exists geographically along transnational supply chains, for
between the WTO and the Convention on Biodiversity, so increasingly cosmopolitan consumers across the world; and
far resolved in favor of the former. But other moves from industrial food, ever more chemically reconstituted, offered
above (McIntyre et al. 2009) and below (Desmarais 2007) to the lowest income consumers across the globe, whose
support culturally and ecologically embedded farming numbers increase as farming systems in the South are
systems. This opens the question of new elements, which displaced by horticulture and aquaculture for sale to the
are potential pivots of a new food regime. global rich. For Campbell, either has the propulsive
potential to consolidate and to legitimate class, inter-state
and regional agri-food relations for a new food regime. In
Conversations between food regimes and science history this he opens the question too quickly foreclosed by those
of us who worry about catastrophic effects of peak oil and
If Pritchard documents one failure to institutionalize new climate chaos: perhaps a food regime based on corporate
relationships, rules, and norms, Campbell and Dixon doc- power and transnational supply chains can impose eco-
ument openings to ever more possible agri-food constel- logical controls, monitored and enforced through audits,
lations since the early 1970s. Each opens a fruitfuland contracts and brands, and convince citizens and consumers
genuinedialogue between food regimes and histories of that they are able to provide food sustainably.7 The other
science. On one side, Campbell applies ecological criteria possibility is harder for those new to ecological perspec-
to contending agri-food projects, and Dixon grounds the tives to envision: regionally organized, ecologically resil-
consumption dimension of food regimes in the history of ient agri-food systems nested into global systems able to
nutrition. On the other, food regime analysis deepens the monitor multiple ecological dimensions.
critical histories of nutritional and ecological sciences, Campbell calls these two contending agri-food systems
technologies and ideologies. The authors show how ide- regimes. While this conceptual innovation may con-
ologies of nutrition (nutritionism) and agricultural fusecoexistence (and contested legitimacy) implies to
industries have changed in tandem with key features of me that regime stabilization has not occurredthis strategy
food regimes. Thus, the UK-centered food regime of the allows him to bring into dialogue divergent interpretations
19th century gives political and global context both to by McMichael and Friedmann. Campbell argues that the
Cronons history of the environmental despoliation impli- two regimes are mutually constitutive: privileged con-
cated in the creation of present grain export regions, and to sumers demand distinctive foods relative to junk food,
the imperial calorie and master protein of global nutri- while poor consumers are multiplied as traditional
tionism; and the US-centered food regime of the years after
7
World War II gives class and policy dynamism both to My summary is no doubt inflected by my own view of a possible
corporate environmental food regime (Friedmann 2005a). Campbell
ecological critiques of mechanicalchemical intensive
has a nuanced argument, giving more weight to the corporate food
agriculture, and to analysis of international power behind from nowhere regime of McMichael. I retain much deeper reserva-
the fortification of industrial foods. These essays give a tions of the ability of capital to regulate itself.

123
Discussion: moving food regimes forward 341

farmers differentiate into those who can meet supermarket strengthened regional fresh markets in advanced coun-
quality criteria and those forced out of farming and into tries, leaving major grains and livestock to industrial
(increasingly corporate) food markets. Ecological theory agriculture. Instead, those farmers and markets were deci-
offers an indicator for comparing their relative sustain- mated by half a century of industrialization of food and
ability, namely feedback mechanisms built into transna- farming, and the poor (in the US) were given surplus
tional versus (interlinked) regional supply chains/networks industrial food, which came to dominate the diets of the
capable of identifying (lack of) ecological resiliency. poor in the North.8 As transnational supply chains move
If crises in food safety continue to occur, and if public into the global South in the prolonged death throes of the
awareness grows that fossil energy, greenhouse gas, water old food regime, both farming systems and local markets
pollution, and loss of soil and biological diversity are are threatened; the growing masses of the poor who can no
profoundly affected by industrial agriculture, then we could longer access fresh foods find that if they can afford any
exit the cycle of food regimes altogether. Food regimes commercial food at all, it is the least healthy and most
have so far privileged power and profit by distancing durable commodities.
ecological effects; as self-organizing spaces reach the As diseases of affluence from the dying food regime
limits of their ability to absorb shocks, something truly new strike the poor in both North and South, nutritionists have
under the sun becomes necessary, and as Campbell shows, publicly dissented from the orthodoxy implicated with
paths to ecologically resilient futures appear in the mist. industrial foods. Nutrition is one of several sciences in
crisis, and is especially connected to public anxieties and
Dixons diagnosis of ontological anxiety mistrust of (conflicting) expert advice. Social movements
and networks, such as Slow Food and Via Campesina, offer
Dixon sees a parallel conflict between two contending alternative visions of regionally embedded agri-food sys-
ways of resolving the increasingly apparent negative health tems, building on longstanding critiques of industrial foods
effects of industrial diets. On one side are industries which have new purchase as diseases and health are
drawing on the newly configured life sciences. Just as increasingly defined as social consequences of food sys-
genetic sciences have reconfigured chemistry, biology, and tems. As social movements, cultural figures, and public
medicine (as well as agronomy), functional foods now agencies kaleidoscopically increase awareness of the health
offer to cure or prevent diseases. Edible industrial com- effects of overly processed foods with concentrated sugar,
modities, which led to sugar, fat, and salt-intensive diets fats, and salt, the dietary response is, as food regimes help
different from anything humans have evolved to eat, are us see, global. Dixon brings in the sociological theories of
now transfigured by biochemical and genetic technologies Habermas to explore these cultural shifts. To cap her
to cure diseases, including those related to poor diets conversation between nutritionism and food regimes,
(Cordain et al. 2005). These integrate old food regime Dixon brings in hegemony. She points out that Oriental-
practices (nutrients and fortification), with new protective ization of cuisines, which is happening in the West as well
nutrients, including the anti-oxidants contained in the as in Asia, not only carries all the contradictions between
very fresh foods lost to eaters of industrial foodfruits, industrial/transnational and artisanal/regional foods, but
vegetable, and fish. Functional foods even promise to tailor also reflects an erratic shift in inter-state power towards
functional foods to individual genetics. Asia.
For Dixon, too, crisis deepens as legitimacy falters
among professional nutritionists and public agencies trying Rethinking nature, society, and science: actor network
to balance economic growth (often defined by corporate theory and food regimes
lobbies) and mounting health costs of aging populations
with diet-related diseases. She brings into food regime The fruitful engagement between food regimes and pro-
analysis the oft-invoked but little understood shift in offi- fessional, public, corporate, and popular understandings of
cial understanding of nutrition. For instance, a food regime science suggests the timeliness of overcoming the mental
perspective allows Dixon to reinterpret the influence of barrier between social and natural sciences. Latour (1993,
Boyd-Orr, the hero of the history of food supplements to p. 134) demonstrates that nature has always infiltrated
the poor as public policynationally and through the Food social accounts and vice versa, since in reality sciences
and Agriculture Organization (FAO). Nutritionism as ide- and societies are co-produced. The task is to make the
ology helps also to appreciate a turning point: the nutrient-
centered approach to poor diets was introduced before 8
Dairy figured centrally in US food programs, as nutritionalist
industrial food became dominant; had the poor been able
beliefs coincided with farm surpluses. This is another contribution,
to purchase enough horticulture and meats from local since the dairy sector has so far received too little attention in food
farms beginning in the 1930s, their purchases would have regime accounts.

123
342 H. Friedmann

multiplication of hybrids visible and undertake the chal- respond to specific experiences of limits and possibilities set
lenge to think differently. Networks, which figure in more by non-human actants. Science helpfully emerges as a con-
and more social and natural theories, allow for this. tested field, with some guidance about how to include it.
Analysis proceeds by tracing networks of actants, ANT gives food regimes more precision. It might help
including bacteria as well as states, genes as well as social resolve some of the terminological and conceptual differ-
movements, maize as well as corporations, watersheds as ences expressed in these essays. Of course, food regimes
well as cities, chickens as well as citizens, fish stocks as also have much to offer ANT.
well as professional scientists, laws as well as sewage
pipes (Latour 1993, p. 117).
Of course, food regimes have also included health and Hegemony redux: power and networks in food regime
ecology, mainly as social movements (e.g. Buttel 1997).9 transition
Dixon and Campbell take food regimes in new directions
by focusing retrospectively as well as prospectively on These essays show the protean quality of food regimes.
aspects of nature and the (constructed) sciences devoted Latour (1993, pp. 75, 141) represents change as a spiral; a
to agriculture and nutrition. Their essays thus belie the vertical line that traverses a cyclical trajectory shows that
inclusion of food regimes with other types of political two points may be closer in meaning than in time. This
economy alleged to [erase] distinctive biological and land- compares to the cyclical times suggested by Arrighi and
based properties (Goodman and Watts 1995, p. 4). Their Silver (1999) for hegemonic transitions: hegemonies share
use of biological and land-based optics on the past opens certain properties, though each occupies a distinct position
to multiple possibilities for completely new constellations on the spiral, with its unique history. Hegemony and
of class, accumulation, power, and all the institutions to transitions bring into focus power, exploitation, accumu-
emerge. These are new elements, not existentially of lation and conflicts which can animate diffuse networks.
course, but institutionallyhealth and ecology were cast Its full meaning according to Gramsci and writ large by
into the margins by the dying regime, with its obsession on Arrighi includes the deeply naturalized beliefs, and insti-
(facilitating growth of) industry and cities. Most political tutions which structure those beliefs, about what exists,
economy, including food regimes, has been caught in the what is possible, and what is right (Therborn 1980).
deep divisions of modernist thought. But the openness of Latour uses a useful metaphor to interpret global and
the approach to include new as well as old elements in local, which evokes the mutual determination of parts and
considering transitional projects of many kinds is very far wholes which McMichael (1990) calls incorporated
from any convenient elision of the problem of transi- comparison. Latour (1993, p. 117) explains that the glo-
tion (Goodman and Watts 1995, p. 3). bal is always local at each point by analogy to a railroad:
Tracing networks of actantshuman, natural, discursive stations and tracks are fixed at any moment, though also
from below complements political economy (Wilkinson changing over time; the tracks dont go everywhere, but
2006) particularly in times of deep change. Classes, for they go far beyond the horizon visible from any station.
instance, can be seen as dissolving (peasantry?), shifting Food regimes can specify fields of contested power shaping
(incipiently global classes of workers, investors, consum- stations and tracks, when they are abandoned and new ones
ers?), and emerging (artisanal, pluriactive, multifunctional, built. It helps to track potential as well as actual con-
and networked agri-food enterprises?). The projects of nections. It helps to track deep changes.
social movements and of multiple individual and collective Food regimes shape historical inquiry by suggesting key
actors arise, interact, and compete in relation to the erratic dates. These dates (if not rigid) recur in so many historical
assertion of bodily and earthly limits to industrial agri-food accounts from so many angles, disciplines, and agendas
systems. We live in the biosphere for sure (though names for that either they identify intersecting turning points in
it can change), but how real are the national states that economy, politics, war, culture, ideas, natural systems,
frame institutions, meanings, identities, even as they become discourse, and more, or they represent naturalized common
multiple (Ruggie 1993)? ANT excels in tracking changing sense in urgent need of deconstruction. Those who balk at
relations among an expanded range of actants, human, nat- any turning points prefer to see change as seamless, mul-
ural, and discursive. This bottom-up approach to change tifaceted, fluid, like the flow of a river. It is partly tem-
follows more precisely what food regimes roughly catego- perament, partly figure-grounddoes one focus on
rize as social movements, civil society, and the like, and finds continuity or discontinuity? Yet these dates are subject to
better ways to understand how specific groups of humans (dis)confirmation. I will close with an example. Canada
sold wheat to the Soviet Union much earlier than expected,
9
My own forays into ecology did not use food regimes, e.g. given the importance of Cold War trade embargoes to US
Friedmann (2000, 2005b). surpluses, which propelled the food regime. Magnans

123
Discussion: moving food regimes forward 343

(forthcoming) investigation of that breach of the trade F.H. Buttel, and P.D. McMichael, 227264. Amsterdam:
blockade led to fascinating insights about USCanada Elsevier.
Friedmann, H. 2005b. Modernity and the hamburger: Cattle and
relations, including explicit pricing and grading practices wheat in ecological and culinary change. Colloquium in agrarian
and implicit export tradeoffs between the two unequal, studies, Yale University. www.yale.edu/agrarianstudies/papers/
closely linked countries. Specific details about mercantile Hamburger.pdf.
practices, negotiated tradeoffs between hegemonic and Friedmann, H., and P. McMichael. 1989. Agriculture and the state
system: The rise and decline of national agricultures, 1870 to the
second-rank powers, and economic dynamics of Cold War present. Sociologia Ruralis 29: 2, 93117.
blocs, gave nuance to regime dynamics. New insights came Goodman, D., B. Sorj, and J. Wilkinson. 1987. From farming to
from dates which were too crude, but useful guides to biotechnology: A theory of agro-industrial development. Oxford:
inquiry. Basil Blackwell.
Goodman, D., and M. Watts. 1995. Reconfiguring the rural or fording
the divide?: Capitalist restructuring and the global agro-food
system. Journal of Peasant Studies 22: 1, 149.
Goodman, D., and M. Watts. 1997. Agrarian questions: Global
appetite, local metabolism: Nature, culture, and industry in fin-
References de-siecle agro-food systems. In Globalizing food: Agrarian
questions and global restructuring, ed. D. Goodman, and M.
Arrighi, G. 1994. The long twentieth century: Money, power, and the Watts, 132. London: Routledge.
origins of our times. London: Verso. Halliday, J. 2009. Normal US access for EU foods is in sight, CIAA.
Arrighi, G., and B. Silver. 1999. Hegemonic transitions: Past and http://www.foodnavigator.com/Legislation/Normal-US-access-for-
present. Political Power and Social Theory 13: 239275. EU-foods-is-in-sight-CIAA/?c=a8SqvLef%2FGJbR14jjGiZ1Q%
Burch, D., and G. Lawrence (eds.). 2007. Supermarkets and agri-food 3D%3D&utm_source=newsletter_daily&utm_medium=email&
supply chains: Transformations in the production and consump- utm_campaign=Newsletter%2BDaily. Accessed 29 July 2009.
tion of food. Cheltenham: Edward Elgar. Independent Commission on International Development Issues [under
Buttel, F.H. 1997. Some observations on agro-food change and the the chairmanship of] W. Brandt. 1980. North-South, A
future of agricultural sustainability movements. In Globalizing programme for survival. Cambridge, MA: MIT Press.
food: Agrarian questions and global restructuring, ed. D. Krasner, S. 1983. Structural causes and regime consequences:
Goodman, and M. Watts, 344365. London: Routledge. Regimes as intervening variables. In International regimes,
Collins, J. 2005. New directions in commodity chain analysis of ed. S. Krasner, 122. Ithaca: Cornell University Press.
global development processes. In New directions in the sociol- Kuyek, D. 2007. Good crop/bad crop: Seed politics and the future of
ogy of international development: Research in rural sociology food in Canada. Toronto: Between the Lines.
and development, vol. 11, ed. F.H. Buttel, and P.D. McMichael, Latour, B. 1993. We have never been modern. Cambridge, MA:
317. Amsterdam: Elsevier. Harvard.
Cordain, L., et al. 2005. Origins and evolution of the Western diet: Magnan, A.J.R. forthcoming. The Canadian Wheat Board, Warbur-
Health implications for the 21st century. American Journal of tons, and the creative reconstitution of the Canada-UK com-
Clinical Nutrition 81: 2, 341354. http://www.ajcn.org/cgi/ modity chain for wheat-bread. PhD thesis, University of
content/full/81/2/341#F4. Accessed 22 July 2009. Toronto.
Crosby, A.W. 1986. Ecological imperialism: The biological expan- McIntyre, B.D., H.R. Herren., J. Wakhungu, and R.T. Watson (eds.).
sion of Europe, 9001900. Cambridge: Cambridge University 2009. International Assessment of Agricultural Knowledge,
Press. Science and Technology for Development Global Report.
Desmarais, A.A. 2007. La va campesina: Globalization and the Washington, DC: Island Press.
power of peasants. Point Black, NS and London: Fernwood McMichael, P. 1984. Settlers and the agrarian question: Foundations
Books & Pluto Press. of capitalism in colonial Australia. Cambridge: Cambridge
Economist 2009. Banking on the fund, mission: Possible, and held in University Press.
reserve, April 1117. McMichael, P. 1990. Incorporating comparison within a world-
Friedmann, H. 1982. Political economy of food: Rise and fall of the historical perspective: An alternative comparative method.
postwar international food order. In Marxist inquiries: Studies of American Sociological Review 55(3): 385397.
labour, class and states, eds. M. Burawoy and T. Skocpol. McMichael, P. 2004. Development and social change: A global
American Journal of Sociology 88 (Suppl.): S248-286. perspective, 3rd ed. Thousand Oaks, CA: Pine Forge Press.
Friedmann, H. 1993. International political economy of food: A Polanyi, K. 1944. The great transformation. New York: Farrar &
global crisis. New Left Review 197, Jan/Feb: 2957. Rinehart.
Friedmann, H. 2000. What on earth is the modern world-system? Ruggie, J. 1993. Territoriality and beyond: Problematizing modernity
Foodgetting and territory in the modern era and beyond. Journal in international relations. International Organization 47: 139
of World-Systems Research 6. http://jwsr.ucr.edu/archive/vol6/ 174.
number2/pdf/jwsr-v6n2-hfriedmann.pdf. Tansey, G., and T. Rajotte (eds.). 2008. The future control of food: A
Friedmann, H. 2004. Feeding the empire: Pathologies of globalized guide to international negotiations and rules on intellectual
agriculture. In The empire reloaded: Socialist register 2005, ed. property, biodiversity and food security. London: Earthscan.
C. Leys, and L. Panitch, 124143. London: Merlin. Therborn, G. 1980. The ideology of power and the power of ideology.
Friedmann, H. 2005a. From colonialism to green capitalism: Social London: Verso.
movements and the emergence of food regimes. In New Wilkinson, J. 2006. Network theories and political economy: From
directions in the sociology of international development: attrition to convergence? In Between the local and the global, ed.
Research in rural sociology and developments, vol. 11, ed. T. Marsden, and J. Murdoch. Amsterdam: Elsevier.

123
344 H. Friedmann

and food and the links between them in the context of (1) diverse
cuisines and agronomies of New Canadians from around the globe,
Author Biography and (2) the food sector as key to creative urban economies. She is a
co-founder of the food regimes approach and has published widely on
Harriet Friedmann is Professor of Sociology at the University of family farms, regional agri-food economies and international political
Toronto Mississauga and at the Centre for International Studies, economy and political ecology of food and agriculture. She works
University of Toronto. Her current research includes the politics of with international agencies concerned with food and agriculture,
food standards at regional, national, and international scales, and the including the recently released International Assessment of Agricul-
innovative community of food practice of Toronto and its surrounding tural Knowledge, Science and Technology.
region. The latter includes the cultural dimension of renewing farming

123

You might also like