You are on page 1of 11

International Review of Financial Analysis 32 (2014) 132–142

Contents lists available at ScienceDirect

International Review of Financial Analysis

Innovation efficiency and asymmetric timeliness of earnings: Evidence


from an emerging market
Ann L.-C. Chan
Department of Accounting, National Chengchi University, 64 Sec. 2 Zhi-Nan Road, Taipei 11605, Taiwan

a r t i c l e i n f o a b s t r a c t

Article history: This study investigates the impact of intellectual capital output on the asymmetric income timeliness of firms in
Received 17 June 2013 Taiwan, which is an emerging economy with a high concentration of research and development (R&D)-intensive
Received in revised form 26 January 2014 firms but poor investor protection. The higher growth opportunities and increased risk faced by R&D firms make
Accepted 29 January 2014
them more vulnerable to shareholder litigation. Specifically, I examine whether companies that are less efficient
Available online 7 February 2014
at transforming new ideas or techniques into granted patents are more timely in their recognition of losses and
JEL classification:
less timely in their recognition of gains in response to higher expected litigation costs. Indeed, I observe a
M41 negative relationship between innovation efficiency and asymmetric income timeliness and this is more evident
among highly R&D-intensive firms. In a parallel analysis, I also find that the observed greater earnings conservatism
Keywords: of low-innovation-efficient firms is more evident following the introduction of the Securities and Futures Investor
Innovation efficiency Protection Act in the year 2003, when a class action litigation mechanism was established. Together, these findings
Asymmetric income timeliness highlight the role of accounting conservatism in mitigating the potential litigation risk faced by high-tech industries.
Information asymmetry © 2014 Elsevier Inc. All rights reserved.
Litigation risk

1. Introduction the value and productivity of firms' R&D investments. Prior studies
show that management may disclose private information through con-
This study examines whether non-financial information based on in- ference calls to reduce R&D-related asymmetric information (Tasker,
novation efficiency reduces asymmetric information and litigation risk. 1998a,b). Unlike these previous studies, I examine the role of patents,
Research and development (R&D) is one of the most important corpo- which are a direct output from R&D activities, in mitigating information
rate strategies that firms have to take, despite the fact that investments asymmetries and reducing litigation risks.
in R&D do not always result in immediate product innovation. Barth and Conservative reporting defers earnings and generates lower net as-
Kasznik (1999) argue that firm investment in intangible assets induces sets and emerges as a defensive response by managers and auditors to
greater information asymmetry than does investment in tangible assets. reduce the likelihood of being sued in a shareholder lawsuit (Watts,
A firm's R&D expenditure is a major contributor to information asym- 2003a). Technology firms are likely to have greater conservative income
metry and the outcome of such innovation inputs plays a key role in as they are subject to both shareholder litigation risk and conservative
mitigating shareholders' concerns about managerial expropriation. A accounting practices (Chandra, 2011). Taiwan is a natural laboratory
less innovation-efficient firm may be more vulnerable to shareholder for studying this issue since it has an economy dominated by high-
litigation than a high innovation-efficient firm that is more capable of tech industries, where investors see R&D as a crucial determinant of
transforming new ideas into granted patents. firm value but are poorly protected by regulation. Shareholders are es-
Specifically, I examine whether innovation efficiency affects conser- pecially sensitive to the agency problems that ensue from R&D expendi-
vative reporting, manifested through less timely gain recognition and tures in intellectual capital-intensive firms as a result of the high
more timely loss recognition. Earnings conservatism facilitates efficient correlation between innovation input (which enhances competitive-
contracting and could increase firm value by reducing contracting and ness) and proprietary information (which reduces disclosure incen-
litigation costs (Watts, 2003a,b). Recent literature confirms the eco- tives). Such agency problems can easily lead to corporate litigation,
nomic benefits of timely loss recognition in financial reporting by especially shareholder litigation. Given the relative lack of transparency
documenting that conservative accounting choices mitigate informa- of Taiwanese financial reporting and the potential inability of the public
tion asymmetry and reduce the costs of capital (e.g. Garcia Lara, Garcia to understand the details released in conference calls about firms'
Osma, & Penalva, 2011). Since R&D and other internally developed in- innovation efforts, patents are important as they certify the credibility
tangibles are generally expensed, investors have little information on of otherwise hard-to-verify voluntary disclosures regarding R&D
successes. The introduction of the Securities and Futures Investor
Protection Act in Taiwan in 2003 also provides a natural choice in
E-mail address: lcchan@nccu.edu.tw. which to observe how an exogenously induced change in the shareholder

1057-5219/$ – see front matter © 2014 Elsevier Inc. All rights reserved.
http://dx.doi.org/10.1016/j.irfa.2014.01.014
A.L.-C. Chan / International Review of Financial Analysis 32 (2014) 132–142 133

litigation environment affects asymmetric income timeliness, especially innovation (Ernst, 2010). Moreover, the nation has been ranked top in
among innovation-intensive firms. By evaluating the impact of this the field of patents by generating one patent for every 2000 persons
regulation, my study also substantiates the view that litigation risk is (Yeo, 2008). These statistical facts make the findings of this study even
one of the main driving forces behind earnings conservatism, especially more interesting and provide out-of-sample evidence regarding the
in high-tech sectors. role of conservatism in mitigating asymmetric information in an
Some argue that it is costly for outside investors to acquire R&D- environment with poor investor protection.
related information since it requires a significant investment in gather- To measure the degree of earnings conservatism, this study applies
ing scientific knowledge, analyzing financial statements, and participat- the Basu (1997) model by regressing reported earnings on stock returns
ing in conference calls (Aboody & Lev, 2000; Hirshleifer, Hsu, & Li, and allowing the return coefficient to change with the sign of the return.
2013). Hirshleifer et al. (2013) indicate that information about new The quantity of patents granted indicates the non-financial attributes of
technologies is difficult for investors to process as it requires knowledge a firm's innovation process, provides valuable information to share-
of how the economic fundamentals are changing as well as an analysis holders, and reduces information asymmetry, agency costs, and expect-
of the innovation process – from the generation of a new idea to the re- ed litigation risk. The results show that innovation efficiency, measured
lease of the final product on the market – since the expected profit is as patent count scaled by R&D capital, is negatively associated with
highly uncertain. Investors may be unable to respond fully and immedi- asymmetric income timeliness. Specifically, companies that are less effi-
ately to the arrival of relevant public information on innovative activi- cient in transforming new ideas into granted patents are more timely in
ties.1 Levitas and Mcfadyen (2009) also argue that new knowledge of recognizing losses and less timely in recognizing gains. Such evi-
innovation may not be easily diffused to external investors, resulting dence is more pronounced among R&D-intensive firms, which face
in knowledge asymmetries between management and external severe information asymmetry and greater expected litigation
suppliers of capital. In the light of these studies, investments in R&D in- costs. In parallel, I seek evidence of the impact of an exogenous
crease a firm's intangible resources but also contribute to the informa- change in the shareholder litigation environment on conservative
tion asymmetry between management and outside investors. reporting. I find that the asymmetric income timeliness is more evident
Existing accounting research documents that conservatism in finan- in the period since the introduction of the Investor Protection Act, when
cial statements facilitates efficient contracting between managers and the shareholder class action litigation mechanism became effective. The
outside investors in the presence of agency problems (e.g. LaFond & effect of this is more pronounced among less innovation-efficient firms
Watts, 2008; Watts, 2003a,b). Watts (2003a) provides four main that are more vulnerable to shareholder class action lawsuits. The
explanations for earnings conservatism – namely, contracting incen- findings of this study contribute to the accounting literature on the
tives, taxation, litigation and regulation – and states that conservative beneficial role of conservatism in financial reporting and highlight the
reporting provides economic benefits from both the contracting and importance of strengthening investor protection mechanisms in devel-
litigation perspectives. Following the registration of patents, the asym- oping economies.
metric information is alleviated as investors acquire wealth benefits The paper is organized as follows. Section 2 reviews the literature
from these investments, which also reduces the probability of share- and develops hypotheses. Section 3 describes the methodology, sample
holder litigation lawsuits. As firms differ in their abilities to convert and data. Section 4 reports the empirical findings. Conclusions are given
R&D into tangible outputs and future performance, I investigate the in Section 5.
extent to which asymmetric income timeliness is conditional on the
success of a firm's R&D efforts. 2. Literature review and hypothesis development
Prior studies show that the asymmetric timeliness of earnings is
higher in periods when shareholder litigation is more prevalent in the 2.1. Institutional environment in Taiwan
US (Basu, 1997; Lobo & Zhou, 2006). Emerging markets generally have
less transparency in their information environments and weaker inves- 2.1.1. Patent disclosures
tor protection than mature markets. In Taiwan, the Securities and Fu- Companies in Taiwan seldom disclose innovative activities in their
tures Investor Protection Act, which went into effect on January 1, financial statements, due to concerns over proprietary costs, and if
2003, aims to ensure the protection of investors by establishing a class they do disclose any information about patents, the majority of that
action litigation mechanism. Since the introduction of the act, firms in information is concerned with patent infringements. Thus, the Taiwan
Taiwan have faced a greater probability of shareholder class action law- Intellectual Property Office's (TIPO) announcement of the number of
suits, which is likely to have induced them to report economic losses in a patents granted each year complements the hard information in finan-
more timely fashion. I exploit this unique setting of an investor protec- cial statements and verifies the soft information of voluntary disclosures
tion regime change in an emerging market to examine the extent to through conference calls, press releases or conversations with analysts.
which mandatory patent granting could alleviate the asymmetric infor- According to the annual statistics provided by TIPO, the majority of pat-
mation and expected litigation costs arising from R&D, thereby reducing ents are granted in the electronics sector.2 Industrial development in
litigation-driven earnings conservatism. The sample comprises firms Taiwan is focused on made-to-order manufacturing services and
listed on the Taiwan Stock Exchange from 2000 to 2008. Compared to researching and developing manufacturing processes so as to attract or-
the world level, business innovation in Taiwan is quite active (Chin, ders from large international companies and improve the efficiency of
Lee, Wang, & Kleinman, 2007). According to the report ‘How technology producing high-tech products. Taiwanese companies are proficient in
sectors grow: Benchmarking IT industry competitiveness 2008’, IT compet- original design and are dominant manufacturers in certain areas, such
itiveness in Taiwan is ranked second in the world, slightly behind that of as desktop personal computers, notebooks, LCD screens, and mother-
the US (Yeo, 2008). The country's strong performance in R&D is the main boards (Einhorn, 2005). In recent years, several companies have pur-
contributor to improvements in IT competitiveness, in an emerging mar- sued an aggressive strategy of filing protective patents in the face of
ket that is strongly connected to the global network of production and increasing global competition. Although there has been rapid growth
in the quantity and quality of innovation carried out by companies in
Taiwan, the high patent count is highly concentrated in terms of
1
As investors may place less weight on information that is more difficult to process, the
limited attention investors pay to innovation activities could lead to return predictability.
Indeed, Hirshleifer et al. (2013) find that innovation efficiency strongly predicts subse-
2
quent stock returns in the US. They argue that investors underreact to information For instance, Taiwanese companies are major global suppliers of made-to-order chips
concerning innovative activities due to the difficulty in evaluating their economic implica- (e.g., Taiwan Semiconductor Manufacturing Co.) and manufacturers of DRAM memory
tions, and that those innovation-efficient firms may be undervalued by investors. chips (e.g. Mosel Vitelic Inc. and Winbond Eletronics Co.).
134 A.L.-C. Chan / International Review of Financial Analysis 32 (2014) 132–142

products and patent holders (Ernst, 2010). Moreover, most patents are 2.2. Innovation activity and information asymmetry
used as tools for self-protection or cross-licensing, and generally have
weak patent citations, science linkages, and technological capabilities Investments in innovation activities generate knowledge, which is
(Liu, 2001). an important input into a firm's production function (Pandit, Wasley,
Public corporations in emerging markets generally have low disclo- & Zach, 2011). Firms with higher rates of success in their innovations
sure quality and their ownership is dominated by pyramid and cross- are likely to exhibit superior future performance. However, innovating
holding structures which exacerbates agency conflicts between the is a highly uncertain process. Kothari, Laguerre, and Leone (2002) find
controlling owners and the minority shareholders (Lee, 2007).3 While that R&D investments generate more uncertain future benefits than
companies in Taiwan engage heavily in innovation activities, the lack investments in fixed assets. Amir, Guan, and Livne (2007) further
of accounting recognition and other appropriate disclosures reduce show that the positive relation between R&D and the volatility of future
the informativeness of financial statements. According to La Porta, earnings described in Kothari et al. (2002) is stronger in R&D-intensive
Lopez-de-Silanes, Shleifer, and Vishny (1998), Taiwan can be catego- industries. Chan, Lakonishok, and Sougiannis (2001) find a positive
rized as part of the Germanic, civil-law group of nations, for which the association between R&D spending and stock return volatility, due to
transparency of the information environment and investor protection investor uncertainty about future payoffs. From the shareholder's view-
are lower than in common-law countries. The lack of clarity or suitable point, the success of R&D activities is indicated by the registration of
regulatory standards and the weak legal enforcement of the financial patents. This enables them to predict the future benefits of R&D.
market and the regulatory reporting agencies in Taiwan result in a rel- Corporate investments generate information asymmetry as insiders
atively opaque information environment. To communicate information have better information than external investors and can continually ex-
to outside investors, traditionally, companies have relied on informal amine the changes in the potential of individual investments, while out-
networking or personal relationships. As the financial market becomes side investors can only gather limited information. The extent of
more developed, an institutional framework involving external codified information asymmetry associated with intangible resources is higher
regulations has appeared, replacing these more informal networking than that with tangibles due to their unique nature and accounting
strategies (Chin et al., 2007). treatments of them (Aboody & Lev, 2000). Information asymmetry be-
tween management and outside investors creates agency costs that, in
turn, impair equity value. All parties involved in the firm have an incen-
2.1.2. Investor protection tive to reduce agency costs by finding mechanisms to make the infor-
The Securities and Futures Investor Protection Act, which went into mation supplied to investors credible. Examples of such mechanisms
effect on January 1, 2003, authorized the government to establish an include better corporate governance, accounting policy choices, and
institution for investor protection. This institution is the Securities and voluntary disclosure (e.g. Gelb, 2002).
Futures Investors Protection Center (SFIPC). The services provided by Prior studies (e.g. Brown, Hillegeist, & Lo, 2004) confirm that
the SFIPC include consultation and mediation, handling investor com- companies may voluntarily disclose information, through confer-
plaints, filing class-action lawsuits on behalf of investors, and managing ence calls and press releases for example, to reduce information
an investor compensation fund. Its role is to strengthen the investor asymmetries. Barth, Kasznik, and McNichols (2001) report that,
protection mechanism and to promote the sound development of the fi- due to the private nature of information regarding R&D, analyst cover-
nancial markets in Taiwan. For any securities investment trading fraud age is significantly greater for R&D-intensive firms than for firms with
involving twenty or more victims, the SFIPC may file lawsuits or an ar- lower levels of R&D or none at all. Furthermore, empirical evidence
bitration application under its own name as an authorized representa- shows that R&D-intensive companies hold more conference calls with
tive of the victims, in accordance with the Investor Protection Act and analysts than do firms engaged in low levels of R&D (Tasker, 1998a),
the SFIPC Charter, which could reduce the total litigation cost and implying that investors have a strong demand for information about
avoid congestion of the court's trial calendars. companies' intangibles, and that the majority of questions raised by an-
The Securities and Exchange Law in Taiwan aims to protect investor alysts in conference calls are R&D and innovation-related (Tasker,
rights and maintain the stock market as a well-functioning platform for 1998b).
financing. The law contains articles that forbid certain types of activities The lack of recognition of R&D outlays as accounting assets in the fi-
that would jeopardize fairness in trading and specifies four major types nancial statements causes differences in beliefs between managers and
of crime: making false financial statements, producing false prospectus- outside investors. The investing public is unable to directly observe the
es, influencing share prices illegally, and insider trading. The SFIPC ana- process of innovation or the success or failure of R&D implementation.
lyzes cases brought by prosecutors to determine whether they involve Given the relative lack of transparency of Taiwanese financial reporting
any of the aforementioned crimes and brings class-action suits on behalf and the difficulty for investors in understanding the details of firms' in-
of investors seeking compensation. Since the introduction of the novation efforts, the use of conference calls appears to be a medium for
Investor Protection Act in 2003, the center has won more than twenty communicating with investors. More innovative firms appear to hold
cases and several are ongoing.4 Among the winning cases, half relate conference calls more frequently (Chin et al., 2007). However, the even-
to misleading prospectus or financial statements, and there is a greater tual output that is indicated by the number of patents granted further
incidence of class action lawsuits among technology firms than other certifies the credibility of the information released through these volun-
firms. If, as has been hypothesized in prior research, earnings conserva- tary disclosures regarding R&D successes.
tism is driven by shareholder litigation, I would expect to observe
higher earnings conservatism in the period since the introduction of 2.3. The role of accounting conservatism
the Investor Protection Act, when the class action lawsuit mechanism
was established. Previous studies identify two types of accounting conservatism: un-
conditional and conditional. Unconditional conservatism is related to
the balance sheet and reflects the understatement of book values of
net assets (e.g., the immediate expensing of R&D or adopting accelerat-
ed depreciation and shorter asset lives). It is unrelated to changes in
3
East Asian firms, including those in Taiwan, are typically majority owned and family future cash flows (news independent). On the other hand, conditional
controlled. Prior studies document that this type of corporate ownership structure reduces
the credibility of reported earnings and is associated with lower earnings informativeness
conservatism is news dependent and earnings related. According to
(e.g., Fan & Wong, 2002). Basu (1997), conditional conservatism is manifested through the asym-
4
Information is available from the SFIPC at http://www.sfipc.org.tw. metric response of earnings to economic gains and losses. Unconditional
A.L.-C. Chan / International Review of Financial Analysis 32 (2014) 132–142 135

conservatism could limit the degree of conditional conservatism, since patents, but also to the predicted superior future performance. As
firms with lower net asset values have less scope to write down im- firms differ in their ability to transform R&D into innovation outputs,
paired assets (Beaver & Ryan, 2005). Moreover, conditional conserva- following Hirshleifer et al. (2013), I define innovation efficiency as num-
tism involves a greater degree of managerial discretion (e.g., ber of patents (patent count) over R&D capital.
restructuring charges, gains and losses on the sale of assets, and the ef- The accounting practice of immediately expensing R&D limits the
fects of discontinued operations) as firms may use different verifiability degree of conditional conservatism. However, the threat of shareholder
criteria to recognize economic gains and losses. Garcia Lara, Garcia litigation may induce managers to accrue losses in a timely fashion. I
Osma, and Mora (2005) show that, in institutional contexts where predict that firms that are less capable of transforming their R&D inputs
there is weaker investor protection and a less dispersed ownership into granted patents (i.e., those with lower R&D success or that are less
structure, earnings management is a significant factor in conditional innovation-efficient) are likely to recognize losses in a timely manner,
(earnings) conservatism. primarily because of accounting choices made in response to the litiga-
Earnings conservatism has significant benefits for financial reporting tion risk that is associated with the highly uncertain future economic
as it addresses moral hazard problems and constrains managers' oppor- benefits of R&D outlays. This leads to the first hypothesis:
tunistic behavior in reporting biased accounting measures. LaFond and
Watts (2008) indicate that conservative reporting is a rational response H1. Less innovation-efficient firms are associated with greater asymmetric
to the information asymmetry between managers and outside inves- income timeliness and this is especially evident among highly R&D-
tors, aimed at lowering the agency costs associated with possible man- intensive firms.
agerial expropriation and helping investors to assess alternative sources
of information regarding equity values. As managers are reluctant to re- In Taiwan, domestic individual investors perform the majority of all
port less-verifiable losses, a lower verification criterion for losses is like- trades. Individual investors tend to be short-term speculators without
ly to elicit information that managers are unwilling to report, implying the resources to undertake fundamental firm research (Chiao, Wang,
that reported loss information is more reliable. Empirical evidence gen- & Lai, 2009). These individual investors are in an economically inferior
erally supports the arguments put forward by Watts (2003a) and position when they encounter any conflict against securities firms or se-
LaFond and Watts (2008) that conservatism is an effective mechanism curities issuers. Once their rights or interests are violated, individual in-
for reducing agency and litigation costs (e.g. Ahmed, Billings, Morton, vestors seldom pursue judicial procedures to protect themselves, due to
& Stanford-Harris, 2002). inadequate information, limited personal capabilities, or high litigation
The litigation explanation puts forth the idea that conservative ac- costs. Class action litigation is commonly exercised as a solution in the
counting, deferring earnings and generating lower net assets emerge US, where victims of the same fraud case are allowed to seek protection
as a defensive response by managers and auditors to reduce the likeli- collectively. Other countries, such as the UK, Japan and Korea, have
hood of being sued in shareholder litigation (Watts, 2003a). Empirical established specialized institutions or funds in charge of investor pro-
studies provide evidence of a greater asymmetric timeliness of earnings tection services.
in periods when shareholder litigation is more prevalent in the US The Investor Protection Act in Taiwan, announced in 2003,
(Basu, 1997; Lobo & Zhou, 2006). At the firm level of analysis, Chandra established a class action litigation mechanism and an investor protec-
(2011) argues that technology firms are likely to be more conservative tion fund, making reference to foreign practices and related consumer
in their reporting than other firms because they are subject to both protection rules. As this act has strengthened the investor protection
higher shareholder litigation risk and conservative accounting practices. mechanism, expected litigation costs are likely to increase due to the in-
These firms display a higher unconditional conservatism due to the re- creased probability of shareholder lawsuits. As shareholder class action
quirement to immediately expense R&D, which is manifested through litigation becomes more prevalent, companies are likely to report more
reduced operating cash flows. On the other hand, conditional conserva- conservatively and this phenomenon should be more pronounced
tism of R&D-intensive firms is mainly driven by litigation risk and is among innovative firms that are less efficient in transforming new
manifested through timely loss recognition, such as asset write- ideas into patents. This leads to the second hypothesis:
downs, restructuring charges and other loss accruals.
H2. Less innovation-efficient firms are associated with greater asymmetric
income timeliness and this is especially evident since the introduction of the
2.4. Hypothesis development
Investor Protection Act.
As the expected litigation costs of the firm increase, liability rules
3. Methodology, sample and data
granting shareholders the right to sue for financial statement misrepre-
sentation generate incentives to recognize economic losses in earnings
To measure the degree of conservative reporting, this study applies
in a more timely fashion (Watts, 2003a,b). The higher growth opportu-
the Basu (1997) framework to capture the asymmetric timeliness of
nities and increased risk faced by R&D-intensive firms make them more
earnings:
vulnerable to shareholder litigation (Francis, Philbrick, & Schipper,
1994; Johnson, Kasznik, & Nelson, 2001; Skinner, 1997). Chandra
(2011) shows that technology firms in the US are more conservative NIit ¼ α 1 þ α 2 DUMit þ α 3 Rit þ α 4 Rit DUMit þ εit ð1Þ
in their reporting, as a result of lower operating cash flows that are
due to the expense of R&D outlays and more income-decreasing ac- where NI is earnings per share scaled by the price at the beginning of the
cruals in response to litigation risk. fiscal year-end, R is the annual return of firm i for year t obtained from
Investors benefit from examining patent-based indicators that re- the monthly returns over the fiscal year, so as to capture any news
flect various aspects of innovation activities. Levitas and Mcfadyen occurring over the accounting period and DUM is a dummy variable tak-
(2009) indicate that patents provide positive signals to external parties, ing the value one when R is negative and zero otherwise. The sign of the
which could increase investors' valuations of a firm and make external return (R) is a proxy for economic gains (good news) or losses (bad
capital more accessible. Pandit et al. (2011) combine the use of R&D ex- news). From Eq. (1), the degree of earnings conservatism depends on
penditure and non-financial measures such as patent counts to shed the extent to which reported earnings contemporaneously reflect
further light on the informational role of R&D and how firms differ in value-relevant news. The intercept (α1) captures the cost of equity
their ability to transform R&D into innovation outputs. They argue and the effect of the previous year's news and α2 has an expected
that their finding that more innovation-efficient firms have a higher value of zero. The slope coefficient α3 indicates the earnings response
market value is not only due to the real option value embedded in the to good news and α4 is the incremental earnings response to bad
136 A.L.-C. Chan / International Review of Financial Analysis 32 (2014) 132–142

news. Unconditional conservatism resulting from the immediate period into before (2000–2002) and after (2003–2008) the Investor
expensing of R&D will exert a negative effect on income that is indepen- Protection Act. As the litigation risk increases after the introduction of
dent of economic news, which will reduce the intercept α1. As fewer as- the act in 2003, and investors have more protection, I would expect
sets are capitalized for R&D-intensive firms, this reduces the scope for the change in the shareholder litigation environment to cause compa-
future impairment, resulting in a lower α4. However, the higher expect- nies to accrue losses in a more timely fashion and for this to be more
ed litigation costs faced by firms with lower R&D success are associated pronounced among the less innovation-efficient firms (i.e. those with
with a greater α4 when managers take asset write-downs or recognize low R&D success).
other losses as a defensive strategy for reducing litigation risk. The control variables are firm size, leverage and the beginning
I report pooled regression results and t-statistics based on Huber– market-to-book ratio. Firm size (SIZE) is measured as the natural
White standard errors. Although the Basu (1997) model has been criti- log of total assets; leverage (LEV) captures firm risk and is calculated
cized in several studies (e.g. Dietrich, Muller, & Riedl, 2007; Givoly, as total liabilities divided by total assets; and the market-to-book
Hayn, & Natarajan, 2007), the asymmetric timeliness of earnings is the ratio (MB) proxies for the investment opportunity set and the degree
most direct indicator of earnings conservatism and Basu's (1997) of past conservatism. I expect LEV to be positively associated with
return-based test has been widely applied in empirical studies. Ball, earnings conservatism due to the demand for efficient debt
Kothari, and Nikolaev (2013) counter the criticisms by showing a formal contracting (LaFond & Watts, 2008; Watts, 2003a). MB reflects both
econometric analysis of Basu's (1997) return-based model. Previous net asset conservatism and firm growth. Net asset conservatism
studies indicate that the market-to-book ratio is associated with the (higher MB) constrains the asymmetric timeliness of earnings,
asymmetric timeliness of earnings (Roychowdhury & Watts, 2007) while greater firm growth is associated with greater information
and that the ratio is an alternative measure of asset recognition that is asymmetry and timely loss recognition (LaFond & Watts, 2008).
correlated with economic leverage (Beaver & Ryan, 2009). To address There is no direct relation between SIZE and timely loss recognition.
the concerns over the use of the return-based test, I control for the Larger firms may report more conservative earnings due to greater
market-to-book ratio, leverage and firm size. political costs. However, information asymmetry may be lower for
Efficiency of innovation activities is measured as the number of pat- larger firms as they are generally more mature and have established
ents (PATNUM) relative to R&D capital in fiscal year t. Following Chan disclosure policies (Ozkan & Ozkan, 2004). Consequently, I do not
et al. (2001) and Hirshleifer et al. (2013), I compute the R&D capital as make a specific prediction about the relation between timely loss
the five-year cumulative R&D expenditure, assuming an annual amorti- recognition and either SIZE or MB.
zation rate of 20%: I collect accounting and market data for companies listed on the
Taiwan Stock Exchange during the period 2000 to 2008, taken from
R&D capital ¼ RDit þ 0:8  RDit−1 þ 0:6  RDit−2 þ 0:4  RDit−3 the Taiwan Economic Journal database. Patent data is collected
þ 0:2  RDit−4 : ð2Þ from the Intellectual Property Office of the Ministry of Economic Af-
fairs. Panel A of Table 1 describes the sample selection. I exclude
I take the natural log of the patent-related measure, as its distri- companies in the financial and utility industries as they are highly
bution is highly skewed and its value is often zero. Thus, the innova- regulated sectors and adopt different accounting practices and
tion efficiency (IE) is calculated as ln[1 + (PATNUM/R&D capital)].5 reporting rules from other sectors. After excluding observations
To examine the impact on asymmetric income timeliness from the with missing accounting data, market data or the innovation
information asymmetry and expected litigation risks arising from R&D
investments, I use earnings before R&D expenditure but after the
imputed R&D amortization expenses scaled by beginning share price, Table 1
assuming an annual amortization rate of 20% (NI⁎). I augment Eq. (1) Sample selection.
to incorporate innovation efficiency and to control for determinants of Panel A: Sample selection criterion
earnings conservatism.
Sample selection criterion Firm-year observations

NI it ¼ β1 þ β2 DUMit þ β3 Rit þ β4 Rit DUM it þ β5 LIEDUM Original sample (all listed Taiwanese 6082
companies 2000–2008)
þβ6 LIEDUMit DUMit þ β7 LIEDUMit Rit þ β8 LIEDUM it Rit DUMit ð3Þ Less: financial and utility companies (494)
Less: missing accounting and market- (811)
þControls þ εit
based data (earnings, annual stock returns,
total liabilities, share prices, total assets,
LIEDUM is a dummy variable equal to one if innovation efficiency market-to-book ratio)
(IE) is less than the yearly median or is equal to zero, and zero other- Less: missing innovation efficiency measure (1367)
Final sample 3410
wise. To test H1, I separate the firms into groups with high and low
R&D intensity based on the yearly median values and perform multivar- Panel B: Industry distribution
iate regression analysis. In response to shareholder litigation, I expect Industry No. of firms No. of obs.
less innovation-efficient firms to be less timely than more innovation-
Automobiles and parts 3 27
efficient firms in recognizing gains, as indicated through a negative β7,
Chemicals and biotechnology 31 206
and more timely in recognizing losses, as indicated through a positive Construction and materials 12 74
β8. This effect will be more pronounced for firms with greater innova- Electrical and mechanical engineering 34 256
tion inputs (i.e. highly R&D-intensive firms) as they are subject to great- Electrical appliances and telecommunications 11 80
Electronic manufacturer 306 1953
er uncertainty over their future performance and have higher expected
Food producers 14 124
litigation costs than other companies. To test H2, I separate the sample General retailers 3 11
Glass and ceramic 5 37
Industrial transportation 5 17
5 Metal 17 109
The measure of innovation efficiency is missing if either the number of patents is miss-
Paper 6 38
ing or R&D capital is missing or zero. As it is difficult to precisely identify the length of the
Plastics 18 129
lags between R&D outlays and successful patent applications, I also consider different al-
Rubber 7 58
ternative deflators. Assuming a two-year lag in the processing of applications, I apply ro-
Textile and fibers 37 291
bustness tests using patent counts scaled by three-year or five-year cumulative R&D
Total 509 3410
expenditures ending in the year t-2. These lead to similar conclusions.
A.L.-C. Chan / International Review of Financial Analysis 32 (2014) 132–142 137

efficiency measure, the final sample includes 3410 firm-year observa- 4. Empirical results
tions for 509 firms. Panel B shows the distribution of the sample by in-
dustry. The majority of the firms are from the electronics sector. This is 4.1. Innovation efficiency and asymmetric timeliness of earnings
supported by the annual statistics provided by TIPO, which show that
most of the top ten organizations in terms of number of patents granted Table 3 reports the impact of innovation efficiency on asymmetric
are manufacturers of electrical and electronic appliances. income timeliness. Before considering a firm's innovation activity,
Table 2 presents summary statistics (Panel A) and correlation analy- the results of the earnings–return regression generally confirm
ses (Panel B). To control for outliers, all variables except patent count those of prior studies. The coefficients reflecting the response of
and innovation efficiency are winsorized at the top and bottom one per- earnings to economic gains (R) and the incremental response of
cent of observations. The mean (median) values of NI⁎ and R are 0.066 earnings to economic losses (R × DUM) are positive and significant.
(0.077) and 0.046 (−0.029) respectively. The average sample firm has LIEDUM captures the different abilities of companies to transform
a MB of 1.494 and LEV of 0.371. The mean R&D intensity (R&D over new ideas into patents and equals one for firms with low innovation
sales) of the sample firms is 3.097%, the mean patent count (PATNUM) efficiency, and zero otherwise. The adjusted R-square of the results,
is 13.527 and the mean value of innovation efficiency (IE) is 0.018. after taking into account innovation efficiency and controlling for
The mean value of the dummy variable for low innovation efficiency several firm-specific characteristics, is 26.60%. The findings confirm
(LIEDUM) is 0.518. The summary statistics indicate a high variability in the prediction that less innovation-efficient firms are generally
the number of patents granted to the sample firms and there are a more conditionally (earnings) conservative. Relative to highly
few companies with a large number of patents. innovation-efficient firms, firms with low efficiency recognize
Panel B of Table 2 reports the Pearson product‐moment and Spear- good news in a less timely manner (IEDUM × R = − 0.036, t =
man rank-order correlations between the variables. The findings from − 2.57), while they are more timely in recognizing bad news
the Pearson and Spearman correlations are generally similar. To facili- (IEDUM × R × DUM = 0.071, t = 1.85). The greater asymmetric in-
tate the discussion, I focus on the Spearman correlations. NI⁎ is signifi- come timeliness reported by less innovation-efficient firms is likely
cantly positively correlated with R, PATNUM, IE, SIZE and MB, and to be driven by the higher expected litigation risk. Turning to the
negatively correlated with LIEDUM and LEV. R&D-intensive firms are control variables, I find that larger companies recognize losses in a
likely to generate more granted patents (PATNUM), and are associated less timely fashion as they are subject to lower information asymmetry.
with higher innovation efficiency (IE) and a higher MB, while these In addition, firms with higher leverage report more conservative
firms are negatively associated with annual share returns, and are likely earnings, as evidenced by the significantly positive coefficient of
to be smaller firms with a lower degree of leverage. Moreover, firms R × DUM × LEV, supporting the claim by Watts (2003a,b) that con-
that are more efficient in transforming R&D inputs into patents make servatism facilitates debt contracting. Roychowdhury and Watts
greater R&D outlays and are associated with better accounting and (2007) show the importance of controlling for the composition
market-based performance measures. of equity values, through the use of the market-to-book ratio in

Table 2
Descriptive statistics and correlation analyses.

Panel A: Descriptive statistics

Variables Mean Median Max Min Stdev

NI⁎ 0.066 0.077 0.436 −0.442 0.142


R 0.046 −0.029 1.972 −0.768 0.532
PATNUM 13.527 0.500 1399.000 0.000 66.128
RD(%) 3.097 1.755 547.744 0.000 10.178
IE 0.018 0.000 3.053 0.000 0.090
LIEDUM 0.518 1.000 1.000 0.000 0.500
SIZE 15.718 15.508 19.603 13.569 1.272
LEV 0.371 0.369 0.762 0.078 0.150
MB 1.494 1.170 6.370 0.260 1.124

Panel B: Correlation analyses

NI⁎ R PATNUM RD(%) IE LIEDUM SIZE LEV MB

NI⁎ 1 0.479 0.095 0.017 0.110 −0.094 0.076 −0.162 0.511


R 0.414 1 0.016 −0.056 0.046 −0.015 0.014 −0.049 0.461
PATNUM 0.045 0.001 1 0.392 0.913 −0.910 0.349 −0.031 0.281
RD(%) −0.029 −0.034 0.040 1 0.283 −0.345 −0.143 −0.237 0.273
IE 0.034 0.030 0.075 −0.020 1 −0.923 0.180 −0.028 0.236
LIEDUM −0.086 −0.010 −0.210 −0.075 −0.212 1 −0.229 0.037 −0.236
SIZE 0.078 0.001 0.347 −0.059 0.028 −0.234 1 0.134 0.093
LEV −0.200 −0.046 −0.001 −0.120 0.015 0.045 0.098 1 −0.112
MB 0.350 0.425 0.181 0.120 0.025 −0.213 0.114 −0.140 1

The overall sample size is 3410 firm-year observations. The table reports summary statistics (Panel A) and correlation analyses (Panel B). All firms are listed on the Taiwan Stock Exchange
from 2000 to 2008 and the data are collected from the Taiwan Economic Journal (TEJ) database and the Intellectual Property Office of the Ministry of Economic Affair. NI⁎ is earnings before
R&D expenses but after the imputed R&D amortization expenses scaled by beginning share price, assuming an annual amortization rate of 20%; R is the annual stock return for firm i for
year t obtained by monthly returns over the fiscal year; PATNUM is the number of patents granted in the year; RD is R&D expenditures over total sales; IE is innovation efficiency calculated
as ln [1 + (PATNUM/R&D capital)]; LIEDUM is a dummy variable equal to one if innovation efficiency (IE) is less than the yearly median or is equal to zero, zero otherwise; SIZE is firm size
measured as natural log of total assets; LEV is leverage measured by the ratio of total liabilities to total assets at the fiscal-year end; and MB is the market-to-book ratio. In Panel B, the lower
left-hand section reports Pearson product-moment correlations while the upper right-hand section reports Spearman rank-order correlations. Bold text indicates significant at 5% level and
italic text indicates significant at 10% level.
138 A.L.-C. Chan / International Review of Financial Analysis 32 (2014) 132–142

Table 3
Innovation efficiency and asymmetric timeliness of earnings.

Predicted sign Coeff. (t-Stat.) Coeff. (t-Stat.) Coeff. (t-Stat.)

Intercept 0.083 (8.74)⁎⁎⁎ 0.084 (6.75)⁎⁎⁎ 0.008 (0.09)


DUM −0.011 (−1.04) −0.007 (−0.36) −0.007 (−0.04)
R + 0.075 (4.52)⁎⁎⁎ 0.095 (7.27)⁎⁎⁎ 0.098 (0.91)
R × DUM + 0.086 (2.72)⁎⁎⁎ 0.040 (1.07) 0.168 (1.69)⁎⁎
LIEDUM −0.001 (−0.10) 0.014 (1.24)
LIEDUM × DUM −0.008 (−0.38) −0.006 (−0.27)
LIEDUM × R − −0.037 (−2.94)⁎⁎⁎ −0.036 (−2.57)⁎⁎⁎
LIEDUM × R × DUM + 0.088 (1.77)⁎⁎ 0.071 (1.85)⁎⁎
SIZE 0.003 (0.50)
SIZE × DUM 0.002 (0.17)
SIZE × R + 0.004 (0.71)
SIZE × R × DUM −/+ −0.014 (−2.08)⁎⁎
LEV −0.060 (−1.77)⁎
LEV × DUM −0.055 (−1.26)
LEV × R − −0.142 (−1.35)⁎
LEV × R × DUM + 0.240 (1.63)⁎
MB 0.027 (3.23)⁎⁎⁎
MB × DUM −0.003 (−0.39)
MB × R − −0.012 (−2.16)⁎⁎
MB × R × DUM −/+ 0.016 (1.00)
Adj R-square (%) 18.13 18.93 26.60

Variables are defined in the notes to Table 2. DUM is a dummy variable taking the value one when R is negative, or zero otherwise. t-statistics in parentheses are based on Huber–White
standard errors clustered by firm and year.
⁎⁎⁎, ⁎⁎, ⁎ indicate statistical significance at 1%, 5%, and 10% level respectively for one-tailed t-tests of coefficients with predicted signs and two-tailed t-tests otherwise.

conservatism tests. The coefficient MB × R is significantly negative, I predict that evidence of firms with low innovation efficiency
consistent with the predicted effect of MB as a proxy for uncondi- being more earnings conservative should appear mainly among
tional (balance sheet) conservatism. those companies with greater investment in R&D. Table 4 reports

Table 4
Innovation efficiency and asymmetric timeliness of earnings, high and low R&D intensity.

Panel A: Median values, high and low R&D intensity

Low R&D intensity High R&D intensity Difference

Variables (Obs. = 1707) (Obs. = 1703) (High–Low)

NI⁎ 0.077 0.076 −0.001


R 0.000 −0.061 −0.060⁎⁎⁎
IE 0.000 0.006 0.006⁎⁎⁎
SIZE 15.639 15.352 −0.287⁎⁎⁎
LEV 0.395 0.340 −0.055⁎⁎⁎
MB 1.000 1.350 0.350⁎⁎⁎

Panel B: Regression analyses

Low R&D intensity High R&D intensity

Predicted sign Coeff. (t-Stat.) Coeff. (t-Stat.) Coeff. (t-Stat.) Coeff. (t-Stat.)

Intercept 0.120 (0.96) 0.119 (0.91) 0.037 (0.36) 0.005 (0.05)


DUM −0.205 (−1.26) −0.222 (−1.22) 0.110 (0.65) 0.125 (0.65)
R + −0.149 (−1.07) −0.090 (−0.54) 0.142 (0.97) 0.217 (1.47)⁎
R × DUM + 0.405 (1.29)⁎ 0.300 (0.91) 0.301 (1.08) 0.049 (0.20)
LIEDUM 0.001 (0.05) 0.017 (1.10)
LIEDUM × DUM 0.007 (0.36) −0.015 (−0.75)
LIEDUM × R − −0.032 (−1.93)⁎⁎ −0.039 (−2.10)⁎⁎
LIEDUM × R × DUM + 0.051 (1.22) 0.093 (2.08)⁎⁎
SIZE −0.002 (−0.29) −0.002 (−0.27) −0.001 (−0.11) 0.001 (0.11)
SIZE × DUM 0.012 (1.09) 0.013 (1.08) −0.004 (−0.35) −0.004 (−0.37)
SIZE × R + 0.019 (1.70)⁎⁎ 0.016 (1.31)⁎ 0.001 (0.24) −0.003 (−0.44)
SIZE × R × DUM −/+ −0.027 (−1.58) −0.023 (−1.23) −0.021 (−1.19) −0.007 (−0.44)
LEV −0.144 (−3.16)⁎⁎⁎ −0.146 (−3.09)⁎⁎⁎ 0.029 (0.40) 0.025 (0.36)
LEV × DUM 0.047 (0.90) 0.049 (0.99) −0.168 (−3.13)⁎⁎⁎ −0.166 (−3.11)⁎⁎⁎
LEV × R − −0.107 (−0.78) −0.104 (−0.76) −0.172 (−1.03) −0.157 (−1.01)
LEV × R × DUM + 0.315 (1.88)⁎⁎ 0.311 (1.87)⁎⁎ 0.210 (0.96) 0.183 (0.85)
MB 0.045 (4.51)⁎⁎⁎ 0.045 (4.55)⁎⁎⁎ 0.022 (2.90)⁎⁎⁎ 0.023 (3.03)⁎⁎⁎
MB × DUM −0.008 (−0.60) −0.008 (−0.58) −0.001 (−0.10) −0.002 (−0.22)
MB × R − −0.022 (−2.03)⁎⁎ −0.025 (−2.23)⁎⁎ −0.008 (−1.55)⁎ −0.009 (−1.90)⁎⁎
MB × R × DUM −/+ 0.023 (0.86) 0.027 (0.98) 0.018 (0.99) 0.018 (0.98)
Adj R-square (%) 31.05 31.09 24.69 24.90

Variables are defined in the notes to Table 2. DUM is a dummy variable taking the value one when R is negative, or zero otherwise. High (low) R&D intensity consists of companies with R&D
expenditures over net sales higher (lower) than the yearly median. t-statistics in parentheses are based on Huber–White standard errors clustered by firm and year. ⁎⁎⁎, ⁎⁎, ⁎ indicate
statistical significance at 1%, 5%, and 10% level respectively for one-tailed t-tests of coefficients with predicted signs and two-tailed t-tests otherwise.
A.L.-C. Chan / International Review of Financial Analysis 32 (2014) 132–142 139

the findings for sub-samples partitioned by R&D intensity. Firms with Table 5 reports the effects of the exogenous increase in litigation risk
R&D intensity greater than the yearly median are included in the highly caused by the introduction of the Investor Protection Act in 2003. Panel A
R&D-intensive group, which consists mainly (around 91% of the sub- reports the median values of the main variables in the sub-periods. The
sample) of companies from the biotechnology, electronics and electrical results indicate that the market-to-book ratio is higher while leverage
equipment sectors. Panel A shows the median values of the main vari- is lower in the period since the introduction of the act. I do not find
ables. The results indicate that more R&D-intensive firms are generally any difference in innovation efficiency before and after the change in
more efficient in getting patents granted and have higher market-to- the shareholder litigation regime. Panel B shows that firms are more
book ratios, while incurring significantly lower share returns and timely in their recognition of losses in the period when litigation risk is
being smaller and lower leveraged. higher.6 Before taking innovation efficiency into account, the coefficient
Panel B of Table 4 reports the regression analyses. I find that, be- capturing the incremental response of earnings to bad news (R × DUM)
fore taking innovation efficiency into account, the response of is significantly positive (0.457, t = 4.53). After considering the impact
earnings to bad news is significant for the highly R&D-intensive of innovation activities, I find that more innovation-efficient firms are
firms (R + R × DUM = 0.142 + 0.301 = 0.443, p-value = 0.06) more timely in recognizing losses only in the period after the introduction
but insignificant for the less R&D-intensive firms. This supports of the Investor Protection Act (R × DUM = 0.233, t = 1.93). However, the
the conjecture that R&D-intensive firms are likely to be more earn- asymmetric income timeliness is more prevalent among firms with
ings conservative in response to greater litigation risks. After con- greater information asymmetry (i.e. less innovation-efficient firms) in
sidering the firms' different capabilities in transforming new ideas that period. In the post-act period, the coefficient of LIEDUM × R is signif-
into patents, the results indicate that highly innovation-efficient icantly negative (−0.031, t = −2.05), that of LIEDUM × R × DUM is sig-
firms in both sub-samples do not display asymmetric income time- nificantly positive (0.098, t = 2.13), and the sum of the coefficients of
liness. However, probably because they face greater litigation costs, LIEDUM × R and LIEDUM × R × DUM is positive and significant, indicating
highly R&D-intensive but less innovation-efficient firms are shown that less innovation-efficient firms are associated with less timely gain
by the results to be more timely in recognizing losses and less timely in recognition and more timely loss recognition than more innovation-
recognizing gains. The coefficient of LIEDUM × R is significantly negative efficient firms. In addition, the findings show that leverage is associated
(−0.039, t = −2.10) and the coefficient LIEDUM × R × DUM is signifi- with timely loss recognition and that larger firms report less conservative
cantly positive (0.093, t = 2.08) in the highly R&D-intensive group. I earnings in the post-act period.
also find that among the less R&D-intensive firms, lower innovation ef- Fig. 2 compares the incremental response of earnings to economic
ficiency is associated with less timely gain recognition but I find no ev- losses before and after the change in the shareholder litigation regime.
idence of timely loss recognition. These findings suggest that less The percentage difference between high and low innovation efficiency
innovation-efficient firms are likely to be more conservative in their is calculated using the coefficients of R × DUM and LIEDUM × R × DUM
reporting, through less timely gain and more timely loss recognition, from Panel B of Table 5. The result shows that the degree of earnings con-
and this is more evident in the highly R&D-intensive firms, which sup- servatism among less innovation-efficient firms is higher than that of
ports the litigation explanation. Of the control variables, LEV is the main highly innovation-efficient firms in both sub-periods, and the difference
determinant of timely loss recognition among low R&D companies. is more pronounced in the post-act period when litigation costs are ex-
Fig. 1 compares the incremental response of earnings to economic pected to be higher. This is consistent with the conjecture that less
losses in high and low R&D-intensive groups. The percentage difference innovation-efficient firms are likely to recognize bad news in a more
between high and low innovation efficiency is calculated using the coef- timely fashion, especially when they are subject to higher litigation risk.
ficients from Panel B of Table 4 (i.e., LIEDUM × R × DUM/R × DUM). It can
be observed that the incremental response of earnings to bad news 4.2. Additional analyses
among less innovation-efficient firms is greater than that of highly
innovation-efficient firms in both high and low R&D groups, and the dif- 4.2.1. Conference calls
ference is more pronounced among highly R&D-intensive companies. It has been documented that management discloses R&D-related in-
This indicates that firms that are less capable of transforming their formation via conference calls in an attempt to reduce asymmetric in-
R&D inputs into granted patents are more likely to recognize losses in formation between themselves and investors (e.g. Chin et al., 2007;
a timely manner, especially among those with high R&D intensity. Tasker, 1998a,b). I thus also examine the role of conference calls in mit-
igating the asymmetry of R&D-related information. The frequencies
with which the companies hold conference calls are hand-collected
200% from China Times. On average, there are conference calls held relating
180% to 21% of the firm-year observations, with the maximum frequency
160% being eight times a year. I further augment Eq. (3) with a dummy vari-
140% able equal to one if firms hold at least one conference call (CALLDUM).
120% Table 6 shows that less R&D-intensive firms that hold conference calls
are associated with the more timely recognition of gains but less timely
100%
Percentage difference recognition of losses. However, I do not find such evidence among
80%
of the incremental
60% earnings response to 6
One could argue that other confounding factors, such as the revised patent law in 2004
40% bad news and changes in accounting rules, may also contribute to the results. However, the conclu-
20% sions of this study are not seriously affected by these factors for the following reasons.
First, I do not find any significant difference in the median values of innovation efficiency
0%
before and after the revised regulations for patents became effective. Second, the process
Low R&D intensity High R&D intensity of gradual convergence to IFRS in Taiwan began in 1999, and so overlaps the entire test pe-
riod of this study. It is possible that, since the convergence to IFRS, management and audi-
Fig. 1. Differential bad news effect between less innovation-efficient and highly innovation- tors have been more conservative in their reporting as a defensive strategy to cope with
efficient firms: comparison of high and low R&D intensity. Percentage difference in the de- the rapid changes in accounting rules and so reduce the possibility of violating these ac-
gree of earnings conservatism between high and low innovation efficiency is calculated counting rules and the expected litigation risks. If this is the case, then earnings conserva-
using the coefficients from Panel B of Table 4. The coefficient of R × DUM and the sum of tism would be steadily increasing over the years. My findings not only show higher
the coefficients of R × DUM and LIEDUM × R × DUM capture the incremental response of earnings conservatism in the period after the year 2003 but further demonstrate that in-
earnings to bad news for highly innovation-efficient and less innovation-efficient firms, novation efficiency plays a role in determining asymmetric income timeliness, mainly in
respectively. the period when the shareholder class action lawsuit had become effective.
140 A.L.-C. Chan / International Review of Financial Analysis 32 (2014) 132–142

Table 5
Innovation efficiency and asymmetric timeliness of earnings, before and after the Securities and Futures Investor Protection Act.

Panel A: Median values, before and after the Securities and Futures Investor Protection Act

Pre-act Post-act Difference

Variables (Obs. = 857) (Obs. = 2553) (Post–Pre)

NI⁎ 0.071 0.077 0.006


R −0.117 −0.006 0.111⁎⁎⁎
IE 0.000 0.002 0.002
SIZE 15.541 15.501 −0.041
LEV 0.388 0.362 −0.025⁎⁎⁎
MB 1.010 1.210 0.200⁎⁎⁎

Panel B: Regression analyses

Pre-act Post-act

Predicted sign Coeff. (t-Stat.) Coeff. (t-Stat.) Coeff. (t-Stat.) Coeff. (t-Stat.)

Intercept 0.336 (1.12) 0.284 (1.04) 0.004 (0.05) −0.012 (−0.11)


DUM −0.312 (−2.29)⁎⁎ −0.228 (−1.10) −0.001 (−0.01) −0.025 (−0.14)
R + 0.026 (0.09) 0.052 (0.18) −0.094 (−0.75) −0.022 (−0.14)
R × DUM + 0.127 (0.17) 0.089 (0.13) 0.457 (4.53)⁎⁎⁎ 0.233 (1.93)⁎⁎
LIEDUM 0.027 (1.37) 0.006 (0.63)
LIEDUM × DUM −0.041 (−0.88) 0.012 (0.60)
LIEDUM × R − −0.009 (−0.51) −0.031 (−2.05)⁎⁎
LIEDUM × R × DUM + 0.005 (0.06) 0.098 (2.13)⁎⁎
SIZE −0.017 (−0.81) −0.015 (−0.75) 0.005 (0.75) 0.005 (0.80)
SIZE × DUM 0.026 (2.40)⁎⁎ 0.022 (1.53) −0.001 (−0.12) 0.000 (−0.01)
SIZE × R + 0.015 (0.83) 0.014 (0.77) 0.010 (1.35)⁎ 0.007 (0.76)
SIZE × R × DUM −/+ −0.009 (−0.18) −0.007 (−0.14) −0.028 (−4.35)⁎⁎⁎ −0.017 (−2.63)⁎⁎⁎
LEV −0.091 (−0.76) −0.101 (−0.98) −0.071 (−2.69)⁎⁎⁎ −0.072 (−2.63)⁎⁎⁎
LEV × DUM −0.229 (−1.79)⁎ −0.215 (−1.69)⁎ 0.014 (0.35) 0.015 (0.42)
LEV × R − −0.453 (−12.43)⁎⁎⁎ −0.449 (−12.80)⁎⁎⁎ 0.016 (0.46) 0.020 (0.63)
LEV × R × DUM + 0.232 (1.55)⁎ 0.230 (1.77)⁎⁎ 0.211 (1.86)⁎⁎ 0.205 (1.89)⁎⁎
MB 0.021 (1.98)⁎⁎ 0.023 (2.16)⁎⁎ 0.024 (2.32)⁎⁎ 0.024 (2.43)⁎⁎
MB × DUM −0.002 (−0.21) −0.005 (−0.54) 0.001 (0.06) 0.001 (0.06)
MB × R − 0.017 (1.79) 0.018 (1.59) −0.007 (−1.28) −0.009 (−1.70)⁎⁎
MB × R × DUM −/+ −0.024 (−1.02) −0.026 (−1.31) 0.018 (0.76) 0.023 (0.87)
Adj R-square (%) 30.59 30.48 26.96 27.11

Variables are defined in the notes to Table 2. DUM is a dummy variable taking the value one when R is negative, or zero otherwise. Pre-act period is 2000–2002 and post-act period is
2003–2008. t-statistics in parentheses are based on Huber–White standard errors clustered by firm and year. ⁎⁎⁎, ⁎⁎, ⁎ indicate statistical significance at 1%, 5%, and 10% level respectively
for one-tailed t-tests of coefficients with predicted signs and two-tailed t-tests otherwise.

highly R&D-intensive firms. For those firms, the coefficient of LIEDUM × non-operating accruals scaled by average total assets across the whole
R (LIEDUM × R × DUM) remains significantly negative (positive) after sample is −0.016. I regress non-operating accruals on LIEDUM and con-
taking conference calls into account. These findings support the results trol for size, leverage and mark-to-book ratio. Untabulated results con-
in Table 4 and substantiate the importance of the granting of patents firm that less innovative firms are associated with more earnings
in certifying the credibility of voluntary disclosures made via conference conservatism, measured by industry-adjusted non-operating accruals
calls, especially among R&D-intensive firms.7 or three-year average non-operating accruals. Further, such evidence is

4.2.2. Corporate governance


Prior studies show that governance mechanisms affect both R&D ac- 45%
tivities (Baysinger, Kosnik, & Turk, 1991) and earnings conservatism 40%
(Ahmed and Duellman, 2007). I thus also include several corporate
35%
governance variables in Eq. (3) as a robustness check. The findings are
robust to board independence, measured by the proportion of indepen- 30%
dent directors on the board, the ownership structure (e.g., institutional 25%
shareholdings, and directors' and supervisors' shareholdings), and dual- 20%
Percentage difference
ity of CEO and President. 15% of the incremental
earnings response to
10%
4.2.3. Alternative measures of earnings conservatism bad news
To address concerns over the use of a return-based test, I use an 5%
accrual-based conservatism proxy. Non-operating accruals are calculat- 0%
ed as total accruals (i.e., net income less cash flow from operations) Pre-act period Post-act period
less operating accruals scaled by total assets, where operating accruals
are estimated by changes in non-cash current assets less changes in cur- Fig. 2. Differential bad news effect between less innovation-efficient and highly
innovation-efficient firms: comparison of pre- and post-act periods. Percentage difference
rent liabilities less depreciation and amortization. The mean value of
in the degree of earnings conservatism between high and low innovation efficiency is
calculated using the coefficients from Panel B of Table 5. The coefficient of R × DUM and
7
Untabulated results show that more innovation-efficient firms are more likely to hold the sum of the coefficients of R × DUM and LIEDUM × R × DUM capture the incremental
conference calls, which implies that the tendency to hold conference calls depends on a response of earnings to bad news for highly innovation-efficient and less innovation-
firm's ability to transform R&D into innovation outputs. efficient firms, respectively.
A.L.-C. Chan / International Review of Financial Analysis 32 (2014) 132–142 141

Table 6
Asymmetric timeliness of earnings and conference calls.

Low R&D intensity High R&D intensity

Predicted sign Coeff. (t-Stat.) Coeff. (t-Stat.) Coeff. (t-Stat.) Coeff. (t-Stat.)

Intercept 0.103 (0.86) 0.096 (0.75) 0.068 (0.57) 0.037 (0.29)


DUM −0.202 (−1.21) −0.213 (−1.11) 0.100 (0.53) 0.115 (0.56)
R + 0.002 (0.01) 0.085 (0.57) 0.155 (0.97) 0.224 (1.35)⁎
R × DUM + 0.204 (0.73) 0.082 (0.29) 0.271 (0.86) 0.047 (0.16)
LIEDUM 0.003 (0.30) 0.017 (1.07)
LIEDUM × DUM 0.004 (0.24) −0.014 (−0.72)
LIEDUM × R − −0.042 (−2.38)⁎⁎⁎ −0.038 (−2.04)⁎⁎
LIEDUM × R × DUM + 0.059 (1.33)⁎ 0.092 (2.23)⁎⁎
CALLDUM 0.003 (0.18) 0.002 (0.09) 0.015 (0.79) 0.016 (0.81)
CALLDUM × DUM −0.013 (−0.38) −0.012 (−0.34) −0.002 (−0.05) −0.001 (−0.03)
CALLDUM × R + 0.057 (1.29)⁎ 0.061 (1.39)⁎ 0.012 (0.52) 0.010 (0.39)
CALLDUM × R × DUM − −0.092 (−2.02)⁎⁎ −0.094 (−2.11)⁎⁎ −0.016 (−0.30) −0.003 (−0.06)
SIZE −0.001 (−0.15) −0.001 (−0.11) −0.003 (−0.36) −0.001 (−0.16)
SIZE × DUM 0.012 (1.02) 0.012 (0.97) −0.003 (−0.26) −0.003 (−0.29)
SIZE × R + 0.009 (0.79) 0.006 (0.42) 0.000 (0.02) −0.004 (−0.41)
SIZE × R × DUM −/+ −0.014 (−0.96) −0.009 (−0.56) −0.019 (−0.92) −0.006 (−0.33)
LEV −0.141 (−3.11)⁎⁎⁎ −0.143 (−3.07)⁎⁎⁎ 0.032 (0.44) 0.029 (0.40)
LEV × DUM 0.041 (0.77) 0.045 (0.87) −0.169 (−3.34)⁎⁎⁎ −0.167 (−3.32)⁎⁎⁎
LEV × R − −0.121 (−0.85) −0.117 (−0.84) −0.160 (−0.93) −0.147 (−0.92)
LEV × R × DUM + 0.321 (1.85)⁎⁎ 0.317 (1.86)⁎⁎ 0.194 (0.87) 0.173 (0.79)
MB 0.043 (4.00)⁎⁎⁎ 0.044 (4.22)⁎⁎⁎ 0.021 (2.58)⁎⁎⁎ 0.022 (2.67)⁎⁎⁎
MB × DUM −0.005 (−0.47) −0.005 (−0.47) −0.001 (−0.07) −0.002 (−0.19)
MB × R − −0.030 (−2.39)⁎⁎⁎ −0.034 (−3.09)⁎⁎⁎ −0.009 (−1.50)⁎ −0.010 (−1.73)⁎⁎
MB × R × DUM −/+ 0.034 (1.25) 0.039 (1.49) 0.018 (0.80) 0.017 (0.78)
Adj R-square (%) 30.34 30.50 24.76 24.94

Variables are defined in the notes to Table 2. DUM is a dummy variable taking the value one when R is negative, or zero otherwise. CALLDUM is a dummy variable equal to one if
firms hold at least one conference call in year t, zero otherwise. High (low) R&D intensity consists of companies with R&D expenditures over net sales higher (lower) than the
yearly median. t-statistics in parentheses are based on Huber–White standard errors clustered by firm and year. ⁎⁎⁎, ⁎⁎, ⁎ indicate statistical significance at 1%, 5%, and 10% level
respectively for one-tailed t-tests of coefficients with predicted signs and two-tailed t-tests otherwise.

more pronounced in the post-act period, when the shareholder class ac- the median daily spread over the fiscal year. The mean and median
tion mechanism is effective, which confirms my conclusions. values of the bid–ask spread are 0.54% and 0.46%. Following Leuz and
Verrecchia (2000), I control for the previous year's share price
4.2.4. Economic consequences of innovation efficiency (PRICE), share turnover (TURNOVER) measured as annual NT$ trading
I further analyze the economic consequences of innovation efficien- volume divided by the market value of outstanding equity, and return
cy. Specifically, I consider the extent to which different capabilities, in volatility (RETVOL), calculated as the annual standard deviation of
terms of converting new ideas into granted patents, influence market li- monthly share returns. I take the natural log of the bid–ask spread
quidity, as measured by the bid–ask spread, which is also commonly and the control variables. Table 7 shows that the coefficient of LIEDUM
used as a proxy for information asymmetry. I estimate the following re- is significantly positive, suggesting that less innovation-efficient firms
gression to investigate the extent to which lower innovation efficiency see a significant decrease in market liquidity relative to more
is associated with information asymmetry and its impact on market innovation-efficient firms. Untabulated results indicate that such evi-
liquidity: dence exists in both highly and less R&D-intensive firms. The model
controlling for industry and year fixed effects explains 41.95% of the
logðBidask spreadit Þ ¼ γ0 þ γ1 LIEDUMit þ γ 2 logðTURNOVERit−1 Þ variation in the bid-ask spreads. Regarding the control variables, the co-
þγ 3 logðPRICEit−1 Þ þ γ4 logðRETVOLi t−1 Þ þ εit : efficients of share turnover and market price are both negative and sig-
ð4Þ nificant, and the coefficient of return volatility is significantly positive,
supporting the findings in prior studies. These results also confirm the
The daily quoted spread is calculated as the difference between the conjecture that innovation efficiency is associated with information
closing bid and ask prices divided by the midpoint. Bid_ask spread is asymmetry.

Table 7
Economic consequences of innovation efficiency.

Dependent variable: log(bid_ask spread)

Predicted sign Coeff. (t-Stat.) Coeff. (t-Stat.)

Intercept −0.984 (−11.44)⁎⁎⁎ −0.611 (−6.20)⁎⁎⁎


LIEDUM + 0.108 (4.44)⁎⁎⁎ 0.123 (5.26)⁎⁎⁎
log(TURNOVER) − −0.141 (−8.49)⁎⁎⁎ −0.180 (−9.34)⁎⁎⁎
log(PRICE) − −0.232 (−12.95)⁎⁎⁎ −0.214 (−9.84)⁎⁎⁎
log(RETVOL) + 0.344 (12.22)⁎⁎⁎ 0.245 (7.40)⁎⁎⁎
Industry fixed effect YES
Year fixed effect YES
Adj R-square (%) 27.37 41.95

log(bid_ask spread) is calculated as the natural log of median daily spread over the fiscal year; LIEDUM is a dummy variable equal to one if innovation efficiency (IE) is less than the yearly
median or is equal to zero, zero otherwise; log(TURNOVER) is natural log of share turnover calculated as annual NT$ trading volume divided by market value of outstanding equity;
log(PRICE) natural log of share price; and log(RETVOL) is natural log of return volatility calculated as the standard deviation of monthly share returns. The control variables are lagged
by one year. After excluding missing values, the sample includes 3342 firm-year observations. t-statistics in parentheses are based on Huber–White standard errors clustered by firm
and year. ⁎⁎⁎, ⁎⁎, ⁎ indicate statistical significance at 1%, 5%, and 10% level respectively for one-tailed t-tests of coefficients with predicted signs and two-tailed t-tests otherwise.
142 A.L.-C. Chan / International Review of Financial Analysis 32 (2014) 132–142

5. Conclusions Beaver, W., & Ryan, S. (2005). Conditional and unconditional conservatism: concepts and
modeling. Review of Accounting Studies, 10(2/3), 269–309.
Beaver, W. H., & Ryan, S. G. (2009). Risky debt, mixed-attribute accounting, and the iden-
Earnings conservatism facilitates efficient contracting and serves as a tification of conditional conservatism. Working paper (Available at: http://papers.
natural defense against litigation. R&D activities cause intangible assets ssrn.com/sol3/papers.cfm?abstract_id=1477528).
Brown, S., Hillegeist, S., & Lo, K. (2004). Conference calls and information asymmetry.
to grow but are also likely to induce asymmetric information between Journal of Accounting and Economics, 37(3), 343–366.
the management and the outside investors and lead to potential share- Chan, L., Lakonishok, J., & Sougiannis, T. (2001). The stock market valuation of research
holder litigation. The granting of patents conveys valuable information and development expenditures. Journal of Finance, 56(6), 2341–2456.
Chandra, U. (2011). Income conservatism in the U.S. technology sector. Accounting
about successful scientific and technological developments and may Horizons, 25(2), 285–314.
mitigate R&D-related information asymmetry and reduce expected liti- Chiao, C., Wang, Z., & Lai, H. (2009). Order submission behaviors and opening price be-
gation risks. haviors: Evidence from an emerging market. Review of Quantitative Finance and
Accounting, 33(2), 253–278.
The empirical evidence of this study implies that the providers and
Chin, C. L., Lee, P., Wang, P. W., & Kleinman, G. (2007). Does innovation matter to the con-
users of financial statements recognize the verifiability of accounting in- ference calls? IEEE Transactions on Engineering Management, 54(4), 699–715.
formation, and further confirms that conservatism is an equilibrium Dietrich, D., Muller, K., & Riedl, E. (2007). Asymmetric timeliness tests of accounting con-
mechanism for mitigating the value reductions and agency costs due servatism. Review of Accounting Studies, 12(1), 95–124.
Einhorn, B. (2005,May 16). Why Taiwan matters: The global economy couldn't function
to information asymmetry. The findings indicate that earnings conser- without it. Business Week, 76–81.
vatism in response to R&D-related asymmetric information and litiga- Ernst, D. (2010). Upgrading through innovation in a small network economy: insights from
tion risk exists mainly in less innovation-efficient firms. This evidence Taiwan's IT industry. Economics of Innovation and New Technology, 19(4), 295–324.
Fan, P. H., & Wong, T. J. (2002). Corporate ownership structure and the informativeness of
is more pronounced among highly R&D-intensive firms. Despite the accounting earnings in East Asia. Journal of Accounting and Economics, 33(3), 401–425.
fact that R&D outlays are generally expensed, which preempts the Francis, J., Philbrick, D., & Schipper, K. (1994). Shareholder litigation and corporate disclo-
level of conditional conservatism through lower recorded assets, my sures. Journal of Accounting Research, 32(2), 137–164.
Garcia Lara, J. M., Garcia Osma, B., & Mora, A. (2005). The effect of earnings management on
findings imply that less innovation-efficient firms recognize losses in a the asymmetric timeliness of earnings. Journal of Business Finance and Accounting,
timely manner (e.g., through larger asset write-offs on recorded assets, 32(3/4), 691–726.
or restructuring charges) as a defense against litigation. Additional anal- Garcia Lara, J. M., Garcia Osma, B., & Penalva, F. (2011). Conditional conservatism and cost
of capital. Review of Accounting Studies, 16(2), 247–271.
yses controlling for conference calls and corporate governance mecha- Gelb, D. S. (2002). Intangible assets and firms' disclosures: An empirical investigation.
nisms confirm the main findings. In parallel, I provide evidence Journal of Business Finance and Accounting, 29(3/4), 457–476.
showing that asymmetric income timeliness exists in the period since Givoly, D., Hayn, C., & Natarajan, A. (2007). Measuring reporting conservatism. The
Accounting Review, 82(1), 65–106.
the shareholder class action mechanism was established and that such
Hirshleifer, D., Hsu, P. H., & Li, D. (2013). Innovation efficiency and stock returns. Journal of
evidence is more pronounced for less innovation-efficient firms. These Financial Economics, 107(3), 632–654.
results may be generalizable to other emerging markets where the in- Johnson, M., Kasznik, R., & Nelson, K. (2001). The impact of securities litigation reform on
formation environment tends to be less transparent. Overall, the find- the disclosure of forward-looking information by high technology firms. Journal of
Accounting Research, 39(2), 297–327.
ings of this study further substantiate the importance of earnings Kothari, S. P., Laguerre, T., & Leone, A. (2002). Capitalization versus expensing: Evidence
conservatism in facilitating efficient contracting and risk reduction, par- on the uncertainty of future earnings from capital expenditures versus R&D outlay.
ticularly in an emerging market characterized by high-technology but Review of Accounting Studies, 7(4), 355–382.
La Porta, R., Lopez-de-Silanes, F., Shleifer, A., & Vishny, R. W. (1998). Law and finance.
with weaker investor protection. Journal of Political Economy, 106(6), 1113–1155.
LaFond, R., & Watts, R. L. (2008). The information role of conservative financial state-
ments. The Accounting Review, 83(2), 447–478.
Acknowledgments Lee, K. (2007). Corporate voluntary disclosure and the separation of cash flow rights from
control rights. Review of Quantitative Finance and Accounting, 28(4), 393–416.
I would like to thank Edward Lee, Cheng-Lung Chin, Steve Lin, and Leuz, C., & Verrecchia, R. E. (2000). The economic consequences of increased disclosure.
Journal of Accounting Research, 38, 91–124 (Suppl.).
participants at the European Accounting Association 2010 annual meet-
Levitas, E., & Mcfadyen, M.A. (2009). Managing liquidity in research-intensive firms: sig-
ing and American Accounting Association 2010 annual congress for naling and cash flow effects of patents and alliance activities. Strategic Management
their valuable comments. I gratefully acknowledge the financial support Journal, 30(6), 659–678.
Liu, S. J. (2001). Competing in the knowledge game: Intellectual property rights. In C. Y.
provided by the National Science Council of Taiwan.
Chang, & P. L. Yu (Eds.), Made by Taiwan: Booming in the information technology era
(pp. 213–234). New Jersey: World Scientific.
References Lobo, G. J., & Zhou, J. (2006). Did conservatism in financial reporting increase after the
Sarbanes–Oxley Act? Initial evidence. Accounting Horizons, 20(1), 57–73.
Aboody, D., & Lev, B. (2000). Information asymmetry, R&D, and insider gains. Journal of Ozkan, A., & Ozkan, N. (2004). Corporate cash holdings: An empirical investigation of UK
Finance, 55(6), 2747–2766. companies. Journal of Banking and Finance, 28(9), 2103–2134.
Ahmed, A., Billings, B., Morton, R., & Stanford-Harris, M. (2002). The role of accounting Pandit, S., Wasley, C. E., & Zach, T. (2011). The effect of R&D inputs and outputs on the re-
conservatism in mitigating bondholder–shareholder conflicts over dividend policy lation between the uncertainty of future operating performance and R&D expendi-
and in reducing debt costs. The Accounting Review, 77(4), 867–890. tures. Journal of Accounting, Auditing and Finance, 26(1), 121–144.
Ahmed, A., & Duellman, S. (2007). Accounting conservatism and board of director charac- Roychowdhury, S., & Watts, R. L. (2007). Asymmetric timeliness of earnings, market-
teristics: An empirical analysis. Journal of Accounting and Economics, 43(2–3), to-book and conservatism in financial reporting. Journal of Accounting and
411–437. Economics, 44(1/2), 2–31.
Amir, E., Guan, Y., & Livne, G. (2007). The association of R&D and capital expenditures Skinner, D. J. (1997). Earnings disclosures and stockholder lawsuits. Journal of Accounting
with subsequent earnings variability. Journal of Business Finance and Accounting, and Economics, 23(3), 249–282.
34(1/2), 222–246. Tasker, S. (1998). Bridging the information gap: Quarterly conference calls as a
Ball, R., Kothari, S. P., & Nikolaev, V. (2013). Econometrics of the Basu asymmetric timeli- medium for voluntary disclosure. Review of Accounting Studies, 3(1/2),
ness coefficient and accounting conservatism. Working paper (Available at: http:// 137–167.
papers.ssrn.com/sol3/papers.cfm?abstract_id=999710). Tasker, S. (1998). Technology company conference calls: A small sample study. Journal of
Barth, M. E., & Kasznik, R. (1999). Share repurchase and intangible assets. Journal of Financial Statement Analysis, 4(1), 6–14.
Accounting and Economics, 28(2), 211–241. Watts, R. L. (2003). Conservatism in accounting Part I: Explanations and implications.
Barth, M. E., Kasznik, R., & McNichols, M. F. (2001). Analyst coverage and intangible assets. Accounting Horizons, 17(3), 207–221.
Journal of Accounting Research, 39(1), 1–34. Watts, R. L. (2003). Conservatism in accounting part II: Evidence and research opportunities.
Basu, S. (1997). The conservatism principle and the asymmetric timeliness of earnings. Accounting Horizons, 17(4), 287–301.
Journal of Accounting and Economics, 24(1), 3–37. Yeo, V. (2008). Taiwan is world's No.2 in IT competitiveness, ZDNet Asia, 16 September 2008.
Baysinger, B.D., Kosnik, R. D., & Turk, T. A. (1991). Effects of board and ownership struc- Available at: http://www.zdnetasia.com/news/business/0,39044229,62046168,00.htm
ture on corporate R&D strategy. Academy of Management Journal, 34(1), 205–214.

You might also like