You are on page 1of 419

Instructor’s Manual on Disk

to accompany

Mathematical Economics
by

Jeffery Baldani
James Bradfield
Robert Turner

Disk 1
( Solutions to problems from Chapters 2, 3, 4, and 5 )
Copyright © 1996 by Harcourt Brace & Company.

All rights reserved. Subject to the restrictions hereof, permission is hereby granted until further
notice, to duplicate this diskette without alteration onto another diskette or the hard disk drive
of a computer for use in connection with a course for which Mathematical Economics, First
Edition, by Jeffery Baldani, James Bradfield and Robert Turner has been adopted, and not for
resale, provided the copies are made from this master diskette only, and provided that the
following copyright notice appears on the label of all copies in diskette form: © 1996 by
Harcourt Brace & Company. The program may not be merged into another program or modified
in any way. Copies may not be made of copies.

Problems and solutions may be displayed and may be reproduced in print form for instructional
purposes only, provided a proper copyright notice appears on the last page of each print-out.

Except as previously stated, no part of the computer program embodied in this diskette may be
reproduced or transmitted in any form or by any means, electronic or mechanical, including input
into or storage in any information system, without permission in writing from the publisher.

Produced in the United States

ISBN: 0-03-011578-7
Table of Contents

Chapter 1 Chapter 4
no problems 4.1 30 – 35
4.2 36 & 37
Chapter 2 4.3 38 & 39
2.1 4 4.4 40 & 41
2.2 5 4.5 42 & 43
2.3 6 4.6 44 – 46
2.4 7 4.7 47 & 48
2.5 8 4.8 49 & 50
2.6 9
2.7 10 Chapter 5
2.8 11 5.1 51 – 54
2.9 12 5.2 55 & 56
2.10 13 & 14 5.3 57
2.11 15 5.4 58 – 60
2.12 16 5.5 61 & 62
2.13 17 5.6 63 – 65
5.7 66 – 68
Chapter 3 5.8 69 & 70
3.1 18
3.2 19
3.3 20
3.4 21
3.5 22
3.6 23
3.7 24
3.8 25
3.9 26
3.10 27
3.11 28
3.12 29

Remaining chapters are on subsequent disks.


2.1
From the text, the solutions to the four cases are:

and

(a)

so when decreases, all solutions except decrease.

(b)

so when decreases, and decrease while the others do not change.

2-1
Harcourt Brace & Company items and derived items copyright © 1996 by Harcourt Brace & Company.
2.2

(a) α is exogenous: its value is not determined within the model.

α is the relative weight put on the goal of income maximization as opposed to rent
maximization.

(b)

(c)

When the solution for rent maximization.

When the solution for income maximization.

2-2
Harcourt Brace & Company items and derived items copyright © 1996 by Harcourt Brace & Company.
2.3

with K fixed

(a)

From FOC,

(b)

2-3
Harcourt Brace & Company items and derived items copyright © 1996 by Harcourt Brace & Company.
2.4

(a)

For

(b)

(i) so

(ii)

2-4
Harcourt Brace & Company items and derived items copyright © 1996 by Harcourt Brace & Company.
2.5

(a)

which holds when

(b)

2-5
Harcourt Brace & Company items and derived items copyright © 1996 by Harcourt Brace & Company.
2.6

Yes, these answers are the same.

2-6
Harcourt Brace & Company items and derived items copyright © 1996 by Harcourt Brace & Company.
2.7

(a)

(b)

(c)

(d)

(e)

The first-order condition for choosing t to maximize T is

which is cubic in t, with no easy solution.

2-7
Harcourt Brace & Company items and derived items copyright © 1996 by Harcourt Brace & Company.
2.8

2-8
Harcourt Brace & Company items and derived items copyright © 1996 by Harcourt Brace & Company.
2.9

(a)

by symmetry

(b)

2-9
Harcourt Brace & Company items and derived items copyright © 1996 by Harcourt Brace & Company.
2.10
(a) Solutions from text:

equation (2.70):

equation (2.71):

equation (2.72):

(b) equilibrium n is when

so

Substituting into solutions for

2-10
Harcourt Brace & Company items and derived items copyright © 1996 by Harcourt Brace & Company.
Note also that

(c)

The first-order condition for choosing t to maximize T is

2-11
Harcourt Brace & Company items and derived items copyright © 1996 by Harcourt Brace & Company.
2.11
(a) From the text,

and

But in this example, c = 0.

(b)

which is the monopoly price.

2-12
Harcourt Brace & Company items and derived items copyright © 1996 by Harcourt Brace & Company.
2.12
(equation (2.84))

2-13
Harcourt Brace & Company items and derived items copyright © 1996 by Harcourt Brace & Company.
2.13

(a)

g > 0 is sufficient for to be positive and finite.

(b) , which is smaller than the usual multiplier,

(c)

When g is larger, there are two possible effects: government spending increases by more
when equilibrium GDP is lower than the target level, but government spending decreases
by more when equilibrium GDP is higher than the target level.

So if the target level is greater than equilibrium GDP,

and a higher value of g will make equilibrium GDP higher.

But if the target level of GDP is lower than equilibrium GDP,

and a higher value of g will make equilibrium GDP lower.

Either way, a higher value of g will move equilibrium GDP closer to the target level.

2-14
Harcourt Brace & Company items and derived items copyright © 1996 by Harcourt Brace & Company.
3.1
(a)

(b) ( 1 x 3 ) row vectors are :

( 2 x 1 ) column vectors are :

3-1
Harcourt Brace & Company items and derived items copyright © 1996 by Harcourt Brace & Company.
3.2
(a)

(b)

(c)

3-2
Harcourt Brace & Company items and derived items copyright © 1996 by Harcourt Brace & Company.
3.3
(a)

(b)

(c)

3-3
Harcourt Brace & Company items and derived items copyright © 1996 by Harcourt Brace & Company.
3.4
(a)

(b) BA is not defined. Since A is a 4x2 matrix and B is a 2x1 vector, the vector products we

would need to calculate to multiply B by A are not defined.

3-4
Harcourt Brace & Company items and derived items copyright © 1996 by Harcourt Brace & Company.
3.5
In matrix form, the given system of equations is:

3-5
Harcourt Brace & Company items and derived items copyright © 1996 by Harcourt Brace & Company.
3.6

Similarly,

3-6
Harcourt Brace & Company items and derived items copyright © 1996 by Harcourt Brace & Company.
3.7

3-7
Harcourt Brace & Company items and derived items copyright © 1996 by Harcourt Brace & Company.
3.8
(a)

(b)

3-8
Harcourt Brace & Company items and derived items copyright © 1996 by Harcourt Brace & Company.
3.9
(a)

3-9
Harcourt Brace & Company items and derived items copyright © 1996 by Harcourt Brace & Company.
3.10
The cofactor matrix for matrix A is :

Now,

Similarly,

Now,

(b) From 3.9, | A | = -40. So,

3-10
Harcourt Brace & Company items and derived items copyright © 1996 by Harcourt Brace & Company.
3.11
The given system of equations can be written as :

Now, the matrix of cofactors is :

We have,

So, solution to the given system of equations is :

x = 3 / 11 , y = 2 / 11, z = - 1 / 11.

3-11
Harcourt Brace & Company items and derived items copyright © 1996 by Harcourt Brace & Company.
3.12
Using Cramer’s Rule :

Now,

3-12
Harcourt Brace & Company items and derived items copyright © 1996 by Harcourt Brace & Company.
4.1

Now,

so,

we know,
so,

(1)

We already derived in eq (4-24) that

(2)

To get the equal prices in the presence of a unit subsidy b1 granted to producers of good 1,

following the reasoning in page 106, we just need to substitute s1 + s11 b1 for s1 in

equations (1) and (2). This gives us the following equilibrium expressions:

Now,

(a)

(b)

P.T.O.
Now,

so,
so,

(iii)

Now,
(iv)

From (iii),

so,

(c)

From (iv),

and then taking partial derivative with respect to b1, we get,

(d)
Interpretations:

If two goods are substitutes, d12 , d21 will be positive,


and s12 , s21 will be positive,
and d11 , d22 always negative,
and s11 , s22 always positive.
Thus,

Thus, a unit increase in subsidy for good A will reduce the price of good A.

Thus, a unit increase in subsidy for good A will increase the price of good B.

Thus, a unit increase in the subsidy for good A will increase the quantity of good A
produced.

We can similarly analyze the effects of a unit increase in subsidy on the quantity of good B
produced.

If two goods are complements, we can interpret equations (a), (b), (c), and (d) in a similar
fashion as above.

We can do similar analyses if two goods are neither complements nor substitutes.
4.2
The equation (4.36) gives us:

For the equilibrium quantities of output of firm 1 to be positive, the signs of the numerator and
the denominator of the R.H.S. of equation (1) has to be the same.

First, assume that they are both negative. Then,

for inequality (3) to be true.


One way of (3) being true is to have:
.
But if:
,
then price is less than both marginal and average cost. In that case, the firm will stop operating.
Therefore, such a case is unlikely.

Now, assume that both the numerator and the denominator are positive.

Then,

and, (4)
One way of (4) being true is to have:
.

That is to say that when

Firm 1's average cost will lie below price.

But, when

Firm 2's average cost will lie above price.

The economics of this is quite clear. Firm 2 is simply not posing any competition to firm 1.
Thus firm 1 can make a positive quantity of goods and sell them at a price that will let the firm
make positive profits.

The case where:

are both positive is discussed in section 4.4.2.

We can interpret other cases when

can be positive in a similar fashion.

The conditions for

to be positive and the interpretations of those conditions


should be a mirror image of those for
.
4.3
Let’s assume we need a tax of rate t.

Then,

We can get equal quantities by substituting


in 4.36.
Thus,

From (4.28),
Now, Let
Then,

or,

(1)

If the value of the R.H.S. of equation (1) is positive, then we need a tax of that amount.
Otherwise, we need a subsidy of that amount.
4.4 Assume

also

Now,

(i)

(ii)

and we also know, (iii)


In matrix form, equations (i), (ii), and (iii) are:

To solve this system, we use Cramer’s Rule.


Now, let’s assume, k = 0.5 Then,

P.T.O If we let c2 = c, then we see that the price in this case will be higher than in
equation 4.48. Thus, everything else being equal, a higher degree of conjectural
variation leads to a higher price in a duopoly.
4.5
The demand function is:
.

Given is:

Now,

(i)

Similarly,

(ii)

And,

(iii)

The matrix form of these conditions is:

We can get the solution of this system from (4.56) by changing the constant c:

(iv)
(v)

Comparing (iv) and (v) with (4.56) and (4.57) respectively, we find that the aggregate triopolist
output and the triopolist price is the same as those of a monopoly with no taxes or subsidies.
4.6
We are given that

and so,

So, from (4.65)

(i)

Similarly,

(ii)

(iii)

So,
a) Now,

So, for a unit upward shift of the inverse demand function, price will change by

Thus, if b = 1, price will go up by

b) In this case,

From (4.65),

(iv)

(v)
Similarly,

(vi)

Since equilibrium total quantity is unchanged, equilibrium price for the industry will be
unchanged.

Comparing (i), (ii), (iii) with (iv), (v), (vi) , we find that
the equilibrium quantity of firm 1 decreases,
the equilibrium quantity of firm 2 increases, and
the equilibrium quantity of firm 3 remains unchanged.
4.7 If

then Equation (4.66) becomes,

Thus, the system in matrix form is:

Now,

a) By Cramer’s Rule:

(1)

b) The multiplier for autonomous spending:

(2)
c) If budget is balanced,

Now, from (1)

(3)

d) The multiplier for autonomous spending in the case of a balanced budget is:

(4)

Equation (1) shows that the equilibrium income will be higher than the income in Equation
(4.70).

Similarly, Equation (2) shows that the multiplier is larger.

Similarly, the balanced budget income and multiplier as specified by Equations (3) and (4) are
higher than those in equations (4.73) and (4.74).
4.8 From (4.82), we know,

So,

(i)

(ii)

(iii)
From Equation (1), we find that an increase in b increases C*. Thus, an increase in marginal
propensity to consume will increase the equilibrium level of consumption. A reduction in tax
rate t will have similar effect on C* as an increase in MPC.

Similarly, we can interpet the roles of other parameters on C*.

The equilibrium values and the rates of changes of can be calculated in a process
similar to that of the calculation of Equations (i), (ii), and (iii).
5.1

(a)

all third derivatives equal 0.

(b)

all third derivatives equal 0.

(c)

(d)
(e)

all second- and third-order cross partial derivatives equal 0


(f)

Now let

and

Then so
and

Now let

and

Then , so

and
5.2
(a)

(b)

(c)

(d)

(e)
(f)
5.3
(a)

(b)

(c)

(d)

(e)

(f)
5.4
(a) at the particular
values of x and y that are of interest.

OR

(b) at the
particular values of x and y that are of interest.

OR
(c) at the particular
values of x and y that are of interest.

OR

(d) at the
particular values of x and y that are of interest.

OR
(e) at the particular
values of x and y that are of interest.

OR

(f) both exist so


exists as long as

at the particular values of x and y that are of interest.

OR
5.5
(a)

(b)
(c)
5.6
(a) the Jacobian
determinant given in the answer to problem 5.5(a),
at the particular values of x and y that are of interest.

(b)
all exist as long as the Jacobian determinant given in the answer to problem 5.5(b),
at the particular values of x, y, and z that are of interest.
(c)
all exist as long as the Jacobian determinant given in the answer to problem 5.5(c),
at the particular values of x, y, and z that are of interest.
5.7

(a) Let . If y =1, then

, or

Note that since two values of x exist for one value of y, x is not a function of y, except in
the locality of particular combinations of x and y.
Evaluated at x = 1 and y = 1,

Evaluated at

and y = 1,

So when x is positive the slope of the level curve becomes more negative when y increases
but if x is negative the slope of the level curve becomes less negative when y increases.

(b) Let . If y =1, then

, or

Note that since two values of x exist for one value of y, x is not a function of y, except in
the locality of particular combinations of x and y.
Evaluated at
x = 1/4 and y = 1,

Evaluated at
and y = 1,

So when x is positive the slope of the level curve becomes more negative when y increases
but if x is negative the slope of the level curve becomes less negative when y increases.

(c) Let . If y =1, then


, or

when evaluated at

.
So the slope of the level curve becomes less negative when y increases.

(d) Let . If y =1, then

, or

when evaluated at

.
So the slope of the level curve becomes less negative when y increases.
(e) Let .
If y = 1, then

, or

when evaluated at

.
So the slope of the level curve becomes less negative when y increases.

(f) Let .
If y = 1, then

, or

when evaluated at

.
So the slope of the level curve becomes less negative when y increases.
5.8
(a)

so homogeneous of degree 2

(b)

so homogeneous of degree 2

(c)

so homogeneous of degree 1

(d)

so homogeneous of degree

(e)

not homogeneous
(f)

so homogeneous of degree 1
Instructor’s Manual on Disk
to accompany

Mathematical Economics
by

Jeffery Baldani
James Bradfield
Robert Turner

Disk 2
( Solutions for Chapters 6 and 7 )
Copyright © 1996 by Harcourt Brace & Company.

All rights reserved. Subject to the restrictions hereof, permission is hereby granted until further
notice, to duplicate this diskette without alteration onto another diskette or the hard disk drive
of a computer for use in connection with a course for which Mathematical Economics, First
Edition, by Jeffery Baldani, James Bradfield and Robert Turner has been adopted, and not for
resale, provided the copies are made from this master diskette only, and provided that the
following copyright notice appears on the label of all copies in diskette form: © 1996 by
Harcourt Brace & Company. The program may not be merged into another program or modified
in any way. Copies may not be made of copies.

Problems and solutions may be displayed and may be reproduced in print form for instructional
purposes only, provided a proper copyright notice appears on the last page of each print-out.

Except as previously stated, no part of the computer program embodied in this diskette may be
reproduced or transmitted in any form or by any means, electronic or mechanical, including input
into or storage in any information system, without permission in writing from the publisher.

Produced in the United States

ISBN: 0-03-011578-7
Table of Contents

Chapter 6 Chapter 7
6.1 4 7.1 43 – 46
6.2 5 7.2 47 – 49
6.3 6 7.3 50
6.4 7 7.4 51 – 56
6.5 8 7.5 57 – 59
6.6 9– 12 7.6 60
6.7 13 & 14 7.7 61
6.8 15 7.8 62
6.9 16 7.9 63 – 67
6.10 17 & 18 7.10 68 & 69
6.11 19 & 20
6.12 21
6.13 22
6.14 23
6.15 24
6.16 25
6.17 26 & 27
6.18 28 – 30
6.19 31
6.20 32
6.21 33 & 34
6.22 35
6.23 36
6.24 37 & 38
6.25 39
6.26 40
6.27 41
6.28 42

Remaining chapters are on subsequent disks.


6.1
Equation (6.2) gives

so
6.2
Equation (6.2) gives

so
6.3
Equation (6.8) gives

so
6.4
As long as dT = dG, the balanced budget multiplier is given by equation (6.9) regardless of

the nature of the income tax system. This can be shown by letting the tax function t be a

function of some parameter, say , as well as income Y, and solving the following system of

equations:

setting dT = dG.
6.5
Equation (6.6) gives

so

if dr = 0 then

As the marginal propensity to consume increases, dY increases. The higher is dG, the

higher is dY. When the Fed makes r constant, we are in the simple Keynesian world with

fixed interest rates. This is called accomodating monetary policy.


6.6

letting dG = dT and dM = 0,

dP is higher the higher is dG since the AD curve shifts higher up the AS curve.

Now, letting N be the numerator and D be the denominator of the expression for dP/dG,
if gets algebraically larger, it becomes smaller in absolute value, that is, less sensitive to interest

rates. This means there is less crowding out, so the AD curve will shift further up the AS curve and

lead to a larger increase in the price level.

the numerator of which equals

Since the denominator is also positive, a greater slope of the AS curve leads to a greater

increase in P when there is a balanced-budget increase in G and T. With a steeper AS curve, more

of the increase in AD translates to higher P and less to higher Y.

the numerator of which equals


Since the denominator is positive, an algebraically larger (smaller in absolute value) sensitivity

of money demand to interest rates leads to a smaller increase in P when there is a balanced-budget

increase in G and T. The less sensitive money demand is to interest rates, the higher interest rates

must go to restore equilibrium in the money market when money demand increases due to higher G.

This leads to more crowding out and a smaller shift of the AD curve.

the numerator of which equals

Since the denominator is positive, a greater MPC leads to a smaller increase in P when there

is a balanced-budget increase in G and T. With a greater MPC, the balanced budget multiplier in

the IS-LM model is smaller. (See equation 6.9.) So the AD curve shifts by less, leading to a smaller

increase in P.

if money demand becomes more sensitive to income, a larger increase in interest rates is needed to

restore equilibrium in the money market since the higher G will create more excess demand for
money. So there is more crowding out and the AD curve will not shift as far up the AS curve.

and

but why the levels of M and P should matter is not clear.


6.7

letting

be such that
dr ,

so or
as G increases, equilibrium Y will increase which should drive P up because of the

upward–sloping AS curve. Accomodating monetary policy strengthens this result.


6.8
so

From the other two equations in the system,

Since

The tax cut has an effect similar to, but smaller in absolute value than, an increase in government

purchases of goods and services. This is because the tax cut causes an increase in autonomous

demand of the marginal propensity to consume times the tax cut whereas the government

purchases increase autonomous demand dollar for dollar.


6.9 From equation (6.10),
6.10
When (the Keynesian model), equation (6.17) implies that

and from equations (6.18) - (6.20),

while

This is the IS-LM model.

When (the Classical model), equation (6.17) implies that becomes

infinitely negative. So from equations (6.18) - (6.20),

;
so when , ; and

so when , .

In the classical model, interest rates and the price level increase sufficiently to choke

off any increase in output.


6.11
Replacing G with M as the argument of the functions in equations (6.11) and differentiating with

respect to M yields
6.12
so

So is larger in absolute value than it used to be, making smaller than

it used to be. As Y starts to increase (and P with it), net exports NX fall, which reduces the

multiplier effect.

: since output doesn't increase by as much, neither does the


demand for money, so interest rates don't rise as much.

:
since aggregate demand doesn't increase by as much, neither does the price level.
6.13
(equation 6.25) so

But from the first-order condition in (6.26),

so

This is an example of the envelope function, discussed in Chapters 13-14.


6.14
so

Differentiating through the FOC with respect to t,

Note that the FOC implies that


6.15
Differentiating equations (6.38) with respect to c,

Using symmetry,
6.16
If

then the FOC for firm i is

Differentiating this with respect to a yields

So

If

The high-cost firm increases output by less. This is because the high-cost firm gets a smaller share

of market output; if market demand increases, the high-cost firm gets a smaller share of the increase

too.
6.17

so the first-order condition is

SOC: or

Differentiating through the first-order condition with respect to a,

Combining the equations for the two firms (i = 1, 2) yields


Using symmetry,

as long as
.
6.18
so the first- and second-order conditions for firm i are

Let . Then differentiating through the FOC with respect to a yields

Putting together these equations for the two firms (i = 1,2) yields
If

then

and

If

then

and
If

then

Note that if there is a parallel shift in the demand curve,

so all of those terms fall out of the expressions above.


6.19 From equation (6.51),

From equation (6.45),

So ,

, and

So
6.20 For the IS curve,

The IS curve is steeper ( is larger in absolute value) the greater are the tax rate
and the marginal propensity to import and the smaller (in absolute value) are the marginal
propensity to consume the sensitivity of investment to income and the sensitivity of
investment to the interest rate As the interest rate r falls, investment increases and so does
output, through the multiplier process. A higher tax rate and marginal propensity to import reduce
the multiplier, while a higher marginal propensity to consume increases it, as does a greater tendency
for investment to increase when output increases. For the IS curve to be steep, there should be a
small multiplier since Y should not increase much when r falls. A small sensitivity of investment to
interest rates yields a steep IS curve because a decrease in the interest rate will not lead to much
increase in investment, and therefore not much increase in output.

For the LM curve,

The LM curve is steeper ( is greater) the larger is the sensitivity of money demand
to income and the smaller are the effect of interest rates on the money supply and the
sensitivity of money demand to interest rates (That is, the less negative is ) For the LM
curve to be steep, it must take a large increase in interest rates to restore equilibrium when an
increase in income increases money demand. This will be the case if money demand is very sensitive
to income and is not very sensitive to interest rates, or if money supply is not very sensitive to
interest rates.
6.21
For the IS curve,

Flexible exchange rates tend to make the IS curve flatter since lower interest rates will
lower the foreign exchange value of the dollar (depending on the magnitude of ), as will higher
income (depending on the magnitude of ), which will increase exports and decrease imports
(depending on the magnitudes of ), leading to a greater increase in output. The IS curve

is steeper ( is larger in absolute value) the greater are the tax rate and the marginal
propensity to import and the smaller (in absolute value) are the marginal propensity to consume
the sensitivity of investment to income and the sensitivity of investment to the interest rate
As the interest rate r falls, investment increases and so does output, through the multiplier process.
A higher tax rate and marginal propensity to import reduce the multiplier, while a higher marginal
propensity to consume increases it, as does a greater tendency for investment to increase when output
increases. For the IS curve to be steep, there should be a small multiplier since Y should not increase
much when r falls. A small sensitivity of investment to interest rates yields a steep IS curve because
a decrease in the interest rate will not lead to much increase in investment, and therefore not much
increase in output.
For the LM curve,

The LM curve is steeper ( is greater) the larger is the sensitivity of money demand
to income and the smaller are the effect of interest rates on the money supply and the
sensitivity of money demand to interest rates (That is, the less negative is ) For the LM
curve to be steep, it must take a large increase in interest rates to restore equilibrium when an
increase in income increases money demand. This will be the case if money demand is very sensitive
to income and is not very sensitive to interest rates, or if money supply is not very sensitive to
interest rates.
6.22
We want to maximize

subject to
,

or to maximize

FOC:

SOC:
6.23
The marginal rate of substitution MRS is defined by

(a)

(b)

(c)

(d)
6.24
(a)

(b)
(c)

(d)
6.25
The marginal rate of technical substitution MRTS is defined as
6.26

(a)

not homogeneous unless

in which case homogeneous of degree 1

(b)

not homogeneous; even if

ln x increases by a factor of , so x increases by a factor of .

(c)

homogeneous of degree 0 if

(d) homogeneous of degree 0.

(e)

homogeneous of degree 0
6.27

From equation (6.67),

so

Now let

The first term in parentheses in the numerator of the expression for dK equals

by the first-order conditions.

Similarly, the third term in parentheses in the numerator of the expression for dK equals

by the first-order conditions.

So dK = 0.
6.28

and
7.1

(a)

SOC: 4 > 0 and so min

(b)
(c)
(d)
(e)
7.2
(a)

(b)
(c)

(d)
(e)
7.3
The answers to all parts follow, corresponding to each part of 7.2:

(a)

(b)

(c)

(d)

(e)
7.4
(a)
(b)
(c)
(d)
(e)
7.5
(a) The derivatives of x*, corresponding to each part of 7.4:

(a)

(b)

(c)

(d)

(e)
(b) The derivatives of y*, corresponding to each part of 7.4:

(a)

(b)

(c)

(d)

(e)
(c) the derivatives of z*, corresponding to each part of 7.4:

(a)

(b)

(c)

(d)

(e)
7.6
By definition 7.1, a function f is concave if
f(x̄)  (1 )f(x̂)  f( x̄  (1 )x̂ )

and f is convex if
f(x̄)  (1 )f(x̂)  f( x̄  (1 )x̂ )

Max ,
n
For a linear function, f(x)
i i
i
1

f(x̄)  (1 )f(x̂)
M a x̄  (1 ) M a x̂
M  a x̄  (1 )a x̂
i i i i i i i i


M a ( x̄  (1 ) x̂ )
f(x̄  (1 ) x̂ )
i i i

So the linear function is concave but not strictly concave, and is convex but not strictly convex.

7-18
Harcourt Brace & Company items and derived items copyright © 1996 by Harcourt Brace & Company.
7.7

From the definition, a concave function f satisfies the inequality

f(x̄)  (1 )f(x̂)  f( x̄  (1 )x̂ )

Let g(x)
f(x) . Then

f(x̄) (1 )f(x̂)  f(x̄  (1 )x̂ )


or
g(x̄)  (1 )g(x̂)  g(x̄  (1 )x̂)

so g is convex.

7-19
Harcourt Brace & Company items and derived items copyright © 1996 by Harcourt Brace & Company.
7.8
Since the functions f and g are concave,

f(x̄)  (1 )f(x̂)  f( x̄  (1 )x̂ )


g(x̄)  (1 )g(x̂)  g( x̄  (1 )x̂ )

Adding the equations,

 f(x̄)  g(x̄)  (1 ) f(x̂)  g(x̂)  f(x̄  (1 )x̂)  g(x̄  (1 )x̂ )


or
h(x̄)  (1 )h(x̂)  h( x̄  (1 ) x̂)

so h is concave.

7-20
Harcourt Brace & Company items and derived items copyright © 1996 by Harcourt Brace & Company.
7.9
(a)
(b)
(c)
(d)
(e)
7.10
The first-order conditions are

(a)

(b)
(c) From equations (7.52),
Instructor’s Manual on Disk
to accompany

Mathematical Economics
by

Jeffery Baldani
James Bradfield
Robert Turner

Disk 3
( Solutions for Chapters 8 and 9 )
Copyright © 1996 by Harcourt Brace & Company.

All rights reserved. Subject to the restrictions hereof, permission is hereby granted until further
notice, to duplicate this diskette without alteration onto another diskette or the hard disk drive
of a computer for use in connection with a course for which Mathematical Economics, First
Edition, by Jeffery Baldani, James Bradfield and Robert Turner has been adopted, and not for
resale, provided the copies are made from this master diskette only, and provided that the
following copyright notice appears on the label of all copies in diskette form: © 1996 by
Harcourt Brace & Company. The program may not be merged into another program or modified
in any way. Copies may not be made of copies.

Problems and solutions may be displayed and may be reproduced in print form for instructional
purposes only, provided a proper copyright notice appears on the last page of each print-out.

Except as previously stated, no part of the computer program embodied in this diskette may be
reproduced or transmitted in any form or by any means, electronic or mechanical, including input
into or storage in any information system, without permission in writing from the publisher.

Produced in the United States

ISBN: 0-03-011578-7
Table of Contents

Chapter 8 Chapter 9
8.1 4 9.1 21 & 22
8.2 5–7 9.2 23 – 26
8.3 8 9.3 27 – 34
8.4 9 & 10 9.4 35 – 37
8.5 11 & 12 9.5 38 – 40
8.6 13
8.7 14
8.8 15
8.9 16
8.10 17
8.11 18
8.12 19 & 20

Remaining chapters are on subsequent disks.


8.1

For this problem, the easiest way to get elasticities is to use logarithms. In general, the elasticity

of x with respect to y equals .

From equation (8.16),

From equation (8.18),

So and

So

8-1
Harcourt Brace & Company items and derived items copyright © 1996 by Harcourt Brace & Company.
8.2
(a)

The value of marginal product of each input equals its price.

(b)

by symmetry,

8-2
Harcourt Brace & Company items and derived items copyright © 1996 by Harcourt Brace & Company.
(c)

diminishing marginal returns to labor

decreasing returns to scale

(d)

8-3
Harcourt Brace & Company items and derived items copyright © 1996 by Harcourt Brace & Company.
(e)

so

The elasticities sum to zero. If input prices and the output price rise by the same percentage,
then the market conditions have not changed in real terms, so output will not change.

(f) Since in equilibrium , we can write

8-4
Harcourt Brace & Company items and derived items copyright © 1996 by Harcourt Brace & Company.
8.3

Letting

since both the numerator and denominator are principal minors of H.

8-5
Harcourt Brace & Company items and derived items copyright © 1996 by Harcourt Brace & Company.
8.4
(a) the FOC are

For each input, the value of marginal product equals the input price.

(b) The SOC are satisfied:

8-6
Harcourt Brace & Company items and derived items copyright © 1996 by Harcourt Brace & Company.
(c) If dP=dw=0,

(d) From the FOC ,

Substituting into the FOC

8-7
Harcourt Brace & Company items and derived items copyright © 1996 by Harcourt Brace & Company.
8.5

(a) the FOC are

(b) The SOC are satisfied:

8-8
Harcourt Brace & Company items and derived items copyright © 1996 by Harcourt Brace & Company.
(c) Since
.

Note we could get this result by treating the FOC as implicit functions:

If dP=dw=0,

8-9
Harcourt Brace & Company items and derived items copyright © 1996 by Harcourt Brace & Company.
8.6
. From equations (8.40),

In perfect competition, so

so the SOC are

8-10
Harcourt Brace & Company items and derived items copyright © 1996 by Harcourt Brace & Company.
8.7
From equation (8.41),

Since
,

If the alternative wage increases, increases by more. They will increase by the
same percentage.

8-11
Harcourt Brace & Company items and derived items copyright © 1996 by Harcourt Brace & Company.
8.8
.

The unit elasticity result will still be obtained from

so the SOC are

8-12
Harcourt Brace & Company items and derived items copyright © 1996 by Harcourt Brace & Company.
8.9

8-13
Harcourt Brace & Company items and derived items copyright © 1996 by Harcourt Brace & Company.
8.10

8-14
Harcourt Brace & Company items and derived items copyright © 1996 by Harcourt Brace & Company.
8.11

(a) For firm 1,

For firm 2,

(b) From the first-order conditions for firm 1,

so

since de > 0.

8-15
Harcourt Brace & Company items and derived items copyright © 1996 by Harcourt Brace & Company.
8.12

For firm x,

For firm y,

8-16
Harcourt Brace & Company items and derived items copyright © 1996 by Harcourt Brace & Company.
(b) Implicitly differentiating the three FOC with respect to c,

8-17
Harcourt Brace & Company items and derived items copyright © 1996 by Harcourt Brace & Company.
9.1
(a)

(b)

(c)

(d)

9-1
Harcourt Brace & Company items and derived items copyright © 1996 by Harcourt Brace & Company.
(e)

(f)

(g)

9-2
Harcourt Brace & Company items and derived items copyright © 1996 by Harcourt Brace & Company.
9.2
(a)

(b)

The second-order conditions are not satisfied globally, but are satisfied at the values of x, y,
and z that solve the first-order conditions (see answer to problem (9.1a):
:

9-3
Harcourt Brace & Company items and derived items copyright © 1996 by Harcourt Brace & Company.
(c)

(d)

9-4
Harcourt Brace & Company items and derived items copyright © 1996 by Harcourt Brace & Company.
(e)

9-5
Harcourt Brace & Company items and derived items copyright © 1996 by Harcourt Brace & Company.
(f)

9-6
Harcourt Brace & Company items and derived items copyright © 1996 by Harcourt Brace & Company.
9.3

9-7
Harcourt Brace & Company items and derived items copyright © 1996 by Harcourt Brace & Company.
9-8
Harcourt Brace & Company items and derived items copyright © 1996 by Harcourt Brace & Company.
9-9
Harcourt Brace & Company items and derived items copyright © 1996 by Harcourt Brace & Company.
9-10
Harcourt Brace & Company items and derived items copyright © 1996 by Harcourt Brace & Company.
9-11
Harcourt Brace & Company items and derived items copyright © 1996 by Harcourt Brace & Company.
9-12
Harcourt Brace & Company items and derived items copyright © 1996 by Harcourt Brace & Company.
9-13
Harcourt Brace & Company items and derived items copyright © 1996 by Harcourt Brace & Company.
9-14
Harcourt Brace & Company items and derived items copyright © 1996 by Harcourt Brace & Company.
9.4

9-15
Harcourt Brace & Company items and derived items copyright © 1996 by Harcourt Brace & Company.
9-16
Harcourt Brace & Company items and derived items copyright © 1996 by Harcourt Brace & Company.
9-17
Harcourt Brace & Company items and derived items copyright © 1996 by Harcourt Brace & Company.
9.5

9-18
Harcourt Brace & Company items and derived items copyright © 1996 by Harcourt Brace & Company.
Now let all exogenous differentials equal 0 except
:

The numerator is (-1) times a border-preserving principal minor of order n-1 of , while the
numerator is a border-preserving principal minor of order n.

By the SOC, the border-preserving principal minors alternate in sign, so the numerator and
the denominator have the same signs.

9-19
Harcourt Brace & Company items and derived items copyright © 1996 by Harcourt Brace & Company.
Now letting all exogenous differentials equal zero except for
,

The numerator is not a border-preserving principal minor of , so it cannot be signed.

9-20
Harcourt Brace & Company items and derived items copyright © 1996 by Harcourt Brace & Company.
Instructor’s Manual on Disk
to accompany

Mathematical Economics
by

Jeffery Baldani
James Bradfield
Robert Turner

Disk 4
( Solutions for Chapter 10 )
Copyright © 1996 by Harcourt Brace & Company.

All rights reserved. Subject to the restrictions hereof, permission is hereby granted until further
notice, to duplicate this diskette without alteration onto another diskette or the hard disk drive
of a computer for use in connection with a course for which Mathematical Economics, First
Edition, by Jeffery Baldani, James Bradfield and Robert Turner has been adopted, and not for
resale, provided the copies are made from this master diskette only, and provided that the
following copyright notice appears on the label of all copies in diskette form: © 1996 by
Harcourt Brace & Company. The program may not be merged into another program or modified
in any way. Copies may not be made of copies.

Problems and solutions may be displayed and may be reproduced in print form for instructional
purposes only, provided a proper copyright notice appears on the last page of each print-out.

Except as previously stated, no part of the computer program embodied in this diskette may be
reproduced or transmitted in any form or by any means, electronic or mechanical, including input
into or storage in any information system, without permission in writing from the publisher.

Produced in the United States

ISBN: 0-03-011578-7
Table of Contents

Chapter 10
10.1 4– 14
10.2 15 – 19
10.2 a 20 & 21
10.2 b 22 – 24
10.2 c 25 & 26
10.2 d & e 27 & 28
10.2 f 29 – 31
10.2 g 32
10.3 33 – 40
10.4 41 – 44
10.5 45
10.6 46
10.7 47
10.8 48
10.9 49
10.10 50
10.11 51
10.12 52 & 53
10.13 54 & 55
10.14 56 & 57
10.15 58
10.16 59
10.17 60 – 65
10.18 66
10.19 67
10.20 68

Remaining chapters are on subsequent disks.


10.1
For parts (a) and (b),
the derivatives of the conditional demand for labor are given by equations (10.9) and (10.10):

while the derivatives of the unconditional demand for labor come from the solution to
equation (10.29):

10-1
Harcourt Brace & Company items and derived items copyright © 1996 by Harcourt Brace & Company.
(a) so

but for this production function,

the SOC of the profit-maximization problem are not satisfied since


:

10-2
Harcourt Brace & Company items and derived items copyright © 1996 by Harcourt Brace & Company.
(b) so

10-3
Harcourt Brace & Company items and derived items copyright © 1996 by Harcourt Brace & Company.
but for this production function,

the SOC of the profit-maximization problem are not satisfied since


:

10-4
Harcourt Brace & Company items and derived items copyright © 1996 by Harcourt Brace & Company.
For parts (c) and (d), the derivatives of the conditional demand for labor function come from
the total differentials of the FOC (10.16), where v is the rental price of input R:

10-5
Harcourt Brace & Company items and derived items copyright © 1996 by Harcourt Brace & Company.
The derivatives of the unconditional demand for labor function can be derived following the
procedure of section 10.3:

10-6
Harcourt Brace & Company items and derived items copyright © 1996 by Harcourt Brace & Company.
The total differentials of the FOC are

10-7
Harcourt Brace & Company items and derived items copyright © 1996 by Harcourt Brace & Company.
(c) so

10-8
Harcourt Brace & Company items and derived items copyright © 1996 by Harcourt Brace & Company.
10-9
Harcourt Brace & Company items and derived items copyright © 1996 by Harcourt Brace & Company.
(d) so

10-10
Harcourt Brace & Company items and derived items copyright © 1996 by Harcourt Brace & Company.
10-11
Harcourt Brace & Company items and derived items copyright © 1996 by Harcourt Brace & Company.
10.2
For the two-input cases, the derivatives of the marginal cost curve come from solving
equation (10.7) for :

10-12
Harcourt Brace & Company items and derived items copyright © 1996 by Harcourt Brace & Company.
For the three-input cases, the derivative of the marginal cost curve with respect to w comes
from solving equation (10.18) while the derivative with respect to output comes from solving
equation (10.23):

For the two-input cases, the derivatives of the conditional demand for labor function with
respect to output come from equation (10.8):

10-13
Harcourt Brace & Company items and derived items copyright © 1996 by Harcourt Brace & Company.
For the three-input cases, the derivatives of the conditional demand for labor function with
respect to output come from solving equation (10.23):

For the two-input case, the derivatives of the unconditional demand for labor function with
respect to price come from equation (10.29) while the slope of the supply curve and the
derivative of the firm's output with respect to w come from equation (10.34):

10-14
Harcourt Brace & Company items and derived items copyright © 1996 by Harcourt Brace & Company.
The same derivatives for the three-input case are similar:

10-15
Harcourt Brace & Company items and derived items copyright © 1996 by Harcourt Brace & Company.
10-16
Harcourt Brace & Company items and derived items copyright © 1996 by Harcourt Brace & Company.
10.2 (a) The derivatives for each production function in problem 10.1 are as follows
(see the answers to problem 10.1 for the formulas and signs of the first and
second derivatives of F):

but

10-17
Harcourt Brace & Company items and derived items copyright © 1996 by Harcourt Brace & Company.
10-18
Harcourt Brace & Company items and derived items copyright © 1996 by Harcourt Brace & Company.
10.2 (b) The derivatives for each production function in problem 10.1 are as follows
(see the answers to problem 10.1 for the formulas and signs of the first and
second derivatives of F):

10-19
Harcourt Brace & Company items and derived items copyright © 1996 by Harcourt Brace & Company.
10-20
Harcourt Brace & Company items and derived items copyright © 1996 by Harcourt Brace & Company.
The slope of the marginal cost curve depends on returns to scale.

which cannot be signed without more information about parameter values.

10-21
Harcourt Brace & Company items and derived items copyright © 1996 by Harcourt Brace & Company.
10.2 (c) The derivatives for each production function in problem 10.1 are as follows
(see the answers to problem 10.1 for the formulas and signs of the first and
second derivatives of F):

(a)

(b)

but

10-22
Harcourt Brace & Company items and derived items copyright © 1996 by Harcourt Brace & Company.
10-23
Harcourt Brace & Company items and derived items copyright © 1996 by Harcourt Brace & Company.
10.2 (d) The unconditional demand for labor does not depend on output; this derivative
is undefined since output is an endogenous variable in the profit maximization
problem.

10.2 (e) The derivatives for each production function in problem 10.1 are as follows
(see the answers to problem 10.1 for the formulas and signs of the first and
second derivatives of F):

(a) but for this production function, the SOC are not satisfied

since
:

(see answer to problem 10.2 (b) for this production function)

is not defined since there is no unique profit-maximizing output level.

(b) but for this production function, the SOC are not satisfied

since
:

10-24
Harcourt Brace & Company items and derived items copyright © 1996 by Harcourt Brace & Company.
(see answer to problem 10.2 (b) for this production function)
is not defined since there is no unique profit-maximizing output level.

but

10-25
Harcourt Brace & Company items and derived items copyright © 1996 by Harcourt Brace & Company.
which cannot be signed without more information about parameter values.

10.2 (f) The derivatives for each production function in problem 10.1 are as follows (see
the answers to problem 10.1 for the formulas and signs of the first and second
derivatives of F):

(a) Since the SOC for the profit-maximization problem are not satisfied for this
production function (see problem 10.2 (b) for this production function), there is no
unique profit-maximizing output level, so there is no supply curve.

(b) Since the SOC for the profit-maximization problem are not satisfied for this
production function (see problem 10.2 (b) for this production function), there is no
unique profit-maximizing output level, so there is no supply curve.

10-26
Harcourt Brace & Company items and derived items copyright © 1996 by Harcourt Brace & Company.
(c) . If the SOC are satisfied,

so

This is easiest to show for this production function by solving explicitly for Q*:

10-27
Harcourt Brace & Company items and derived items copyright © 1996 by Harcourt Brace & Company.
(d) . If the SOC are satisfied,

so
.

The SOC do not hold for all parameter values, though.

10-28
Harcourt Brace & Company items and derived items copyright © 1996 by Harcourt Brace & Company.
10.2 (g) The derivatives for each production function in problem 10.1 are as follows
(see the answers to problem 10.1 for the formulas and signs of the first and
second derivatives of F):

(a) As in part f, this derivative does not exist for this production function because
there is no unique Q*.

(b) As in part f, this derivative does not exist for this production function because
there is no unique Q*.

(c) The easiest way to derive this derivative for this production function is to solve
explicitly for Q* (see problem 10.2 (f) for this production function):

10-29
Harcourt Brace & Company items and derived items copyright © 1996 by Harcourt Brace & Company.
10.3
The Hicksian demand derivatives come from the expenditure minimization problem of
Chapter 9:

10-30
Harcourt Brace & Company items and derived items copyright © 1996 by Harcourt Brace & Company.
The Marshallian demand derivatives come from the utility maximization problem of
Chapter 9:

10-31
Harcourt Brace & Company items and derived items copyright © 1996 by Harcourt Brace & Company.
(a) so

The Marshallian derivatives in this case are most easily derived by solving explicitly for the
demand functions:

10-32
Harcourt Brace & Company items and derived items copyright © 1996 by Harcourt Brace & Company.
(b) so

The Marshallian derivatives in this case are most easily derived by solving explicitly for the
demand functions:

10-33
Harcourt Brace & Company items and derived items copyright © 1996 by Harcourt Brace & Company.
(c) so

10-34
Harcourt Brace & Company items and derived items copyright © 1996 by Harcourt Brace & Company.
The Marshallian derivatives in this case are most easily derived by solving explicitly for the
demand functions:

10-35
Harcourt Brace & Company items and derived items copyright © 1996 by Harcourt Brace & Company.
(d) so

10-36
Harcourt Brace & Company items and derived items copyright © 1996 by Harcourt Brace & Company.
10-37
Harcourt Brace & Company items and derived items copyright © 1996 by Harcourt Brace & Company.
10.4
The Marshallian demand derivatives come from the utility maximization problem of
Chapter 9:

10-38
Harcourt Brace & Company items and derived items copyright © 1996 by Harcourt Brace & Company.
(a) so

(b) so

10-39
Harcourt Brace & Company items and derived items copyright © 1996 by Harcourt Brace & Company.
(c) so

10-40
Harcourt Brace & Company items and derived items copyright © 1996 by Harcourt Brace & Company.
(d) so

10-41
Harcourt Brace & Company items and derived items copyright © 1996 by Harcourt Brace & Company.
10.5

10-42
Harcourt Brace & Company items and derived items copyright © 1996 by Harcourt Brace & Company.
10.6

Substitutability or complementarity in production depends on what happens to the demand for


one input when the price of another input changes. These effects are symmetric: if an
increase in the price of input j causes an increase in the demand for input i, then an increase
in the price of input i causes an increase in the demand for input j. This symmetry holds for
both conditional and unconditional input demands. (But it is possible for two inputs to be
substitutes as defined by the effects on conditional input demands and complements as
defined by the effects on unconditional demands.)

10-43
Harcourt Brace & Company items and derived items copyright © 1996 by Harcourt Brace & Company.
10.7

SOC: Border-preserving principal minors of order r of have sign

10-44
Harcourt Brace & Company items and derived items copyright © 1996 by Harcourt Brace & Company.
10.8

10-45
Harcourt Brace & Company items and derived items copyright © 1996 by Harcourt Brace & Company.
10.9

10-46
Harcourt Brace & Company items and derived items copyright © 1996 by Harcourt Brace & Company.
10.10

If the compensated demand for good i increases when the price of good j increases, then the
compensated demand for good j will increase when the price of good i increases, and the
goods are substitutes. But because the income effects may differ, this symmetry does not
necessarily hold for the uncompensated (ordinary) demands. It is not so obvious what the
concepts of substitutability and complementarity mean in terms of ordinary demand functions.

10-47
Harcourt Brace & Company items and derived items copyright © 1996 by Harcourt Brace & Company.
10.11
maximize

subject to

which are identical to equations (10.42) if


.

which is the same as equation (10.43).

10-48
Harcourt Brace & Company items and derived items copyright © 1996 by Harcourt Brace & Company.
10.12
From equations (10.52)

10-49
Harcourt Brace & Company items and derived items copyright © 1996 by Harcourt Brace & Company.
10-50
Harcourt Brace & Company items and derived items copyright © 1996 by Harcourt Brace & Company.
10.13
From equations (10.52)

10-51
Harcourt Brace & Company items and derived items copyright © 1996 by Harcourt Brace & Company.
since from the FOC

so

10-52
Harcourt Brace & Company items and derived items copyright © 1996 by Harcourt Brace & Company.
10.14

maximize

subject to

10-53
Harcourt Brace & Company items and derived items copyright © 1996 by Harcourt Brace & Company.
SOC not sufficient to sign numerator

10-54
Harcourt Brace & Company items and derived items copyright © 1996 by Harcourt Brace & Company.
10.15 From equations (10.56)

A higher value of implies that increasing C2 yields more extra utility than before, while the
marginal utility of C1 is the same as before. Thus total utility can be increased by buying less
C1 and more C2.
Said another way,

has to equal 1 + r, so if the marginal utility of C2 increases then


we have to have less C1 to raise

and more C2 to lower


.

10-55
Harcourt Brace & Company items and derived items copyright © 1996 by Harcourt Brace & Company.
10.16
From equations (10.50),

So

Thus

and .

10-56
Harcourt Brace & Company items and derived items copyright © 1996 by Harcourt Brace & Company.
10.17
From equation (10.63), the substitution effect is given by . From (10.60),

From the FOC (10.59),

so the substitution effect is

(a) so

10-57
Harcourt Brace & Company items and derived items copyright © 1996 by Harcourt Brace & Company.
10-58
Harcourt Brace & Company items and derived items copyright © 1996 by Harcourt Brace & Company.
(b) so

10-59
Harcourt Brace & Company items and derived items copyright © 1996 by Harcourt Brace & Company.
Now let . Then

Let . Then

10-60
Harcourt Brace & Company items and derived items copyright © 1996 by Harcourt Brace & Company.
so

and the substitution effect is

(c) so

10-61
Harcourt Brace & Company items and derived items copyright © 1996 by Harcourt Brace & Company.
10-62
Harcourt Brace & Company items and derived items copyright © 1996 by Harcourt Brace & Company.
10.18
consumer 1:

consumer 2:

The condition for Pareto efficiency is that

From the FOC,

10-63
Harcourt Brace & Company items and derived items copyright © 1996 by Harcourt Brace & Company.
10.19
consumer 1:

consumer 2:

The condition for Pareto efficiency is that

From the FOC,

10-64
Harcourt Brace & Company items and derived items copyright © 1996 by Harcourt Brace & Company.
10.20
for each consumer s:

The condition for Pareto efficiency is that for any two individuals s and r,

. From the FOC,

10-65
Harcourt Brace & Company items and derived items copyright © 1996 by Harcourt Brace & Company.
Instructor’s Manual on Disk
to accompany

Mathematical Economics
by

Jeffery Baldani
James Bradfield
Robert Turner

Disk 5
( Solutions for Chapter 11, 12, 13 and 14 )
Copyright © 1996 by Harcourt Brace & Company.

All rights reserved. Subject to the restrictions hereof, permission is hereby granted until further
notice, to duplicate this diskette without alteration onto another diskette or the hard disk drive
of a computer for use in connection with a course for which Mathematical Economics, First
Edition, by Jeffery Baldani, James Bradfield and Robert Turner has been adopted, and not for
resale, provided the copies are made from this master diskette only, and provided that the
following copyright notice appears on the label of all copies in diskette form: © 1996 by
Harcourt Brace & Company. The program may not be merged into another program or modified
in any way. Copies may not be made of copies.

Problems and solutions may be displayed and may be reproduced in print form for instructional
purposes only, provided a proper copyright notice appears on the last page of each print-out.

Except as previously stated, no part of the computer program embodied in this diskette may be
reproduced or transmitted in any form or by any means, electronic or mechanical, including input
into or storage in any information system, without permission in writing from the publisher.

Produced in the United States

ISBN: 0-03-011578-7
Table of Contents

Chapter 11 Chapter 13
11.1 4–7 13.1 60
11.2 8 – 10 13.2 61
11.3 11 – 20 13.3 62
11.4 21 – 27 13.4 63 & 64
11.5 28 – 31 13.5 65
11.6 32 & 33 13.6 66 – 68
13.7 69 – 72
Chapter 12
12.1 34 Chapter 14
12.2 35 14.1 73 – 75
12.3 36 14.2 76
12.4 37 & 38 14.3 77
12.5 39 – 41 14.4 78
12.6 42 – 44 14.5 79 – 80
12.7 45 14.6 81 – 84
12.8 46 & 47
12.9 48
12.10 49
12.11 50 – 52
12.12 53
12.13 54
12.14 55 & 56
12.15 57
12.16 58
12.17 59

Remaining chapters are on subsequent disks.


11.1

(a)

so check

so

(b)

SOC: and

(c)

so check

so so max not min

11-4
Harcourt Brace & Company items and derived items copyright © 1996 by Harcourt Brace & Company.
(d)

so check

so so max not min

(e)

so check

so so max not min

11-5
Harcourt Brace & Company items and derived items copyright © 1996 by Harcourt Brace & Company.
(f)

so check

when

11-6
Harcourt Brace & Company items and derived items copyright © 1996 by Harcourt Brace & Company.
SOC:

so

(g)

z = 3/2 y = 1/2 x=1

SOC:

so

11-7
Harcourt Brace & Company items and derived items copyright © 1996 by Harcourt Brace & Company.
11.2

(a)

so check

so so min not max

(b)

SOC: and

(c)

so check

so so min not max

11-8
Harcourt Brace & Company items and derived items copyright © 1996 by Harcourt Brace & Company.
(d)

so check

when

SOC:

so

11-9
Harcourt Brace & Company items and derived items copyright © 1996 by Harcourt Brace & Company.
(e) ,

SOC:

so

11-10
Harcourt Brace & Company items and derived items copyright © 1996 by Harcourt Brace & Company.
11.3

There are two ways to approach these problems: (1) assume that the constraint will be binding,
solve the first-order conditions for optimizing the Lagrangian, and check to see that all choice
variables and the Lagrange multiplier are positive (if not, check border solutions or redo the
problem with a slack constraint); and (2) assume that the constraint will not be binding (that is,
do Problem 11.1) and check to see that the constraint is slack (if not, redo the problem taking
the constraint into account).

(a)

11-11
Harcourt Brace & Company items and derived items copyright © 1996 by Harcourt Brace & Company.
Since

we might try doing the problem as unconstrained (see Problem 11.1a) which leads to the solution

which does indeed satisfy the constraint. Or, since solving the FOC for the Lagrangian leads to

we might try optimizing the Lagrangian assuming the border condition that

so

Since

the constraint is slack so the solution to the constrained problem is

11-12
Harcourt Brace & Company items and derived items copyright © 1996 by Harcourt Brace & Company.
(b)

These first-order conditions are highly nonlinear and not easy to solve, so we will hope that the
constraint is not binding and solve the problem with a slack constraint (see Problem 11.1b),
which yields as solutions

These do indeed satisfy the constraint:

so the solution to the constrained problem is the same as the solution to the unconstrained
problem:

11-13
Harcourt Brace & Company items and derived items copyright © 1996 by Harcourt Brace & Company.
(c)

Since
,
we might try doing the problem as unconstrained (see Problem 11.1c) which leads to the solution
,
which does not satisfy the constraint. Or, since solving the FOC for the Lagrangian leads to
,
we might try optimizing the Lagrangian assuming the border condition that

so

11-14
Harcourt Brace & Company items and derived items copyright © 1996 by Harcourt Brace & Company.
When

so the solution to the constrained problem is

(d)

Since
,
we try doing the problem as unconstrained (see Problem 11.1d) which leads to the solution
,
which does indeed satisfy the constraint. So the solution to the constrained problem is the same
as the solution to the unconstrained problem:

11-15
Harcourt Brace & Company items and derived items copyright © 1996 by Harcourt Brace & Company.
(e)

These first-order conditions are nonlinear and not easy to solve, so we will hope that the
constraint is not binding and solve the problem with a slack constraint (see Problem 11.1e),
which yields as solutions

These do indeed satisfy the constraint:

so the solution to the constrained problem is the same as the solution to the unconstrained
problem:

11-16
Harcourt Brace & Company items and derived items copyright © 1996 by Harcourt Brace & Company.
(f)

11-17
Harcourt Brace & Company items and derived items copyright © 1996 by Harcourt Brace & Company.
11-18
Harcourt Brace & Company items and derived items copyright © 1996 by Harcourt Brace & Company.
Since
,
we might try doing the problem as unconstrained (see Problem 11.1f) which leads to the solution
,
which does indeed satisfy the constraint. Or, since solving the FOC for the Lagrangian leads to
,
we might try optimizing the Lagrangian assuming the border condition that

so

Since
,
the constraint is slack so the solution to the constrained problem is

11-19
Harcourt Brace & Company items and derived items copyright © 1996 by Harcourt Brace & Company.
(g)

since all four variables are positive, the solution is

11-20
Harcourt Brace & Company items and derived items copyright © 1996 by Harcourt Brace & Company.
11.4

There are two approaches to this problem: assume that the constraint will be binding, solve the
first-order conditions for optimizing the Lagrangian, and see if the Lagrange multiplier or any
of the choice variables are negative (if they are, redo the problem assuming the constraint is slack
and/or check border conditions); or assume that the constraint will be slack and check to see if
the constraint is binding at the values of the choice variables that minimize the objective function
(if they are, redo the problem as a Lagrangian).

(a)

Since all three variables are positive, the solution to the constrained minimization problem is

11-21
Harcourt Brace & Company items and derived items copyright © 1996 by Harcourt Brace & Company.
(b)

Since
,
the constraint is slack, so solve the problem as an unconstrained problem (see Problem 11.2b),
which yields

This does satisfy the constraint, so the solution to the constrained minimization problem is

11-22
Harcourt Brace & Company items and derived items copyright © 1996 by Harcourt Brace & Company.
(c)

Since
,
the constraint is slack, so we could solve the problem as an unconstrained problem (see Problem
11.2c), which yields

which does indeed satisfy the constraint. Or we could try setting

and optimizing the Lagrangian


:

Since
,
the constraint is slack, so the solution to the constrained minimization problem is the solution to
the unconstrained problem,

11-23
Harcourt Brace & Company items and derived items copyright © 1996 by Harcourt Brace & Company.
(d)

11-24
Harcourt Brace & Company items and derived items copyright © 1996 by Harcourt Brace & Company.
11-25
Harcourt Brace & Company items and derived items copyright © 1996 by Harcourt Brace & Company.
Since solving the FOC for the Lagrangian leads to
,
we should try optimizing the Lagrangian assuming the border condition that

so

Since all variables are positive, this gives the solution to the constrained problem:

11-26
Harcourt Brace & Company items and derived items copyright © 1996 by Harcourt Brace & Company.
(e)

So

indicating that the constraint is slack. The unconstrained minimum is achieved at

(see Problem 11.2e). At these values, the constraint is satisfied, so the solution to the constrained

minimization problem is the same as the solution to the unconstrained minimization problem:

11-27
Harcourt Brace & Company items and derived items copyright © 1996 by Harcourt Brace & Company.
11.5

(a)

so

11-28
Harcourt Brace & Company items and derived items copyright © 1996 by Harcourt Brace & Company.
(b)

so

11-29
Harcourt Brace & Company items and derived items copyright © 1996 by Harcourt Brace & Company.
(c)

By graphing or by searching all nodes, we find that the middle constraint is not binding at the

optimum. So

This leaves

11-30
Harcourt Brace & Company items and derived items copyright © 1996 by Harcourt Brace & Company.
Evaluated at

11-31
Harcourt Brace & Company items and derived items copyright © 1996 by Harcourt Brace & Company.
11.6

(a)

(b)

11-32
Harcourt Brace & Company items and derived items copyright © 1996 by Harcourt Brace & Company.
(c)

11-33
Harcourt Brace & Company items and derived items copyright © 1996 by Harcourt Brace & Company.
12.1
From equation (12.3), x = 0 when
.

(a) so

This is a contradiction, so x cannot equal 0.

(b) so

(c) so and

But if x = 0, This is a contradiction, so x cannot equal 0.

12-1
Harcourt Brace & Company items and derived items copyright © 1996 by Harcourt Brace & Company.
12.2
By graphing or by trial and error it can be determined that the optimum occurs at the intersection
of the two constraints

So 0

So .

Each extra calorie required increases the minimum expenditure by


cents.

12-2
Harcourt Brace & Company items and derived items copyright © 1996 by Harcourt Brace & Company.
12.3

(a)

(b)

so relaxing the second constraint (adding more testers) would add more to profits.

12-3
Harcourt Brace & Company items and derived items copyright © 1996 by Harcourt Brace & Company.
12.4

(a) & (b) If both kinds of computers are made,

If

then both Lagrange multipliers are positive, so both constraints are binding,

If

so the first constraint is not binding. Thus the firm can choose any combination of B and U that
satisfies the second constraint.

If the firm chooses to make only basic computers, it can make B = 160,
leading to profits of 16,000.
If the firm chooses to make only upscale computers, it can make U = 80,
leading to profits of

since

So the firm should make only basic computers.

12-4
Harcourt Brace & Company items and derived items copyright © 1996 by Harcourt Brace & Company.
If

so the second constraint is not binding. Thus the firm can choose any combination of B and U
that satisfies the first constraint.

If the firm chooses to make only basic computers, it can make B = 200,
leading to profits of 20,000.
If the firm chooses to make only upscale computers, it can make
U= ,
leading to profits of

since

So the firm should make only upscale computers.

12-5
Harcourt Brace & Company items and derived items copyright © 1996 by Harcourt Brace & Company.
12.5

12-6
Harcourt Brace & Company items and derived items copyright © 1996 by Harcourt Brace & Company.
So and the second constraint is not binding. Thus

so B = 0.

12-7
Harcourt Brace & Company items and derived items copyright © 1996 by Harcourt Brace & Company.
Thus

The solution is for the firm to make only upscale computers.

12-8
Harcourt Brace & Company items and derived items copyright © 1996 by Harcourt Brace & Company.
12.6

12-8
Harcourt Brace & Company items and derived items copyright © 1996 by Harcourt Brace & Company.
So and the second constraint is not binding. Thus

12-9
Harcourt Brace & Company items and derived items copyright © 1996 by Harcourt Brace & Company.
so B = 0.

Thus

The solution is for the firm to make only upscale computers.

12-10
Harcourt Brace & Company items and derived items copyright © 1996 by Harcourt Brace & Company.
12.7

12-11
Harcourt Brace & Company items and derived items copyright © 1996 by Harcourt Brace & Company.
12.8

12-12
Harcourt Brace & Company items and derived items copyright © 1996 by Harcourt Brace & Company.
If the first constraint is not binding and
,

12-13
Harcourt Brace & Company items and derived items copyright © 1996 by Harcourt Brace & Company.
12.9

From the constraints, it follows that


.

12-14
Harcourt Brace & Company items and derived items copyright © 1996 by Harcourt Brace & Company.
12.10

The firm will hold no inventories if the first constraint is binding.

12-15
Harcourt Brace & Company items and derived items copyright © 1996 by Harcourt Brace & Company.
12.11

The firm wants to maximize profits, which equal


.

12-16
Harcourt Brace & Company items and derived items copyright © 1996 by Harcourt Brace & Company.
(a) If

then

so the first constraint is not binding and


.
If the first constraint is not binding and
,

Since

12-17
Harcourt Brace & Company items and derived items copyright © 1996 by Harcourt Brace & Company.
(b) The firm would choose to hold no inventories if the first constraint is binding,

that is if

This will happen if

12-18
Harcourt Brace & Company items and derived items copyright © 1996 by Harcourt Brace & Company.
12.12

We are told that the profit constraint is binding and that capital is needed for production,
so those two first-order conditions hold with equality. The Kuhn-Tucker conditions can
therefore be written as

(a) If

(b) Yes, if the less expensive labor was sufficiently unproductive :


If

12-19
Harcourt Brace & Company items and derived items copyright © 1996 by Harcourt Brace & Company.
12.13
. If L = 0 then

So, when evaluated at C = I and L = 0,

, or

(a) If
,

so

(b) If
,

so

12-20
Harcourt Brace & Company items and derived items copyright © 1996 by Harcourt Brace & Company.
12.14
We want to maximize

subject to
.
The Lagrangian is

If both constraints are binding (the representative consumer is liquidity constrained), all four
partial derivatives of the Lagrangian equal zero, which yields as solutions

If

which means that the first constraint is not binding (there is no liquidity constraint), and
.
When

and
,
the solutions are:

12-21
Harcourt Brace & Company items and derived items copyright © 1996 by Harcourt Brace & Company.
12-22
Harcourt Brace & Company items and derived items copyright © 1996 by Harcourt Brace & Company.
12.15
.

If the constraint is binding and both choice variables are positive,

If the consumer is liquidity constrained, S = 0 and


, so

Note that if

the condition for being liquidity constrained is


,
just as in the text. The higher is , the less likely it is that the consumer will be liquidity
constrained. This makes sense since a higher value of means that the consumer values
second-period consumption more, so would be less likely to borrow from second-period
income in order to finance more first-period consumption.

12-23
Harcourt Brace & Company items and derived items copyright © 1996 by Harcourt Brace & Company.
12.16
From equation (12.26),

so

12-23
Harcourt Brace & Company items and derived items copyright © 1996 by Harcourt Brace & Company.
12.17
Maximize

subject to

If both constraints are binding (the representative consumer is liquidity constrained), all four
partial derivatives of the Lagrangian equal zero, which yields as solutions

If

which means that the first constraint is not binding (there is no liquidity constraint).

So the condition under which the consumer will be liquidity constrained is

or .

12-24
Harcourt Brace & Company items and derived items copyright © 1996 by Harcourt Brace & Company.
13.1
The demand function is:

The cost function is:

We assume that g < a

If the monopolist wants to maximize profit, then the objective function is:

The optimal value for Q is:

So, the value function for the monopolist is:

13-1
Harcourt Brace & Company items and derived items copyright © 1996 by Harcourt Brace & Company.
13.2
Here,

Objective function,

13-2
Harcourt Brace & Company items and derived items copyright © 1996 by Harcourt Brace & Company.
13.3
From 13.1, we have the value function,

Thus, the effect of a shift of the inverse demand function is:

(1)

The effect of a unit decrease in the fixed costs is:

(2)

Equating (1) and (2), we get the condition on parameters:

13-3
Harcourt Brace & Company items and derived items copyright © 1996 by Harcourt Brace & Company.
13.4
The consumer’s utility function is:

The budget constraint is:

Now,

(1)

(2)

(3)

Multiplying (1) by and (2) by we get:

(4)

13-4
Harcourt Brace & Company items and derived items copyright © 1996 by Harcourt Brace & Company.
Now, let

Similarly,

So, the value function is:

13-5
Harcourt Brace & Company items and derived items copyright © 1996 by Harcourt Brace & Company.
13.5
From 13.4, we have,

Similarly,

Now,

So, the marginal utility of income is

(1)

Similarly, (2)

The marginal effects of the prices and on utility are given by equations (1) and (2).

13-6
Harcourt Brace & Company items and derived items copyright © 1996 by Harcourt Brace & Company.
13.6
The consumer’s utility function is:

The budget constraint is:


Now,

(1)

(2 )

(3)

Solving (1) and (2) we get:

Now substituting this value of into eq (3), we get,

13-7
Harcourt Brace & Company items and derived items copyright © 1996 by Harcourt Brace & Company.
So, the value function is:

13-8
Harcourt Brace & Company items and derived items copyright © 1996 by Harcourt Brace & Company.
(b) From equation (1), we have,

Now,

So, the marginal utility of income is 10.

Another way of looking at marginal utility of income is,

The analysis for are similar.

13-9
Harcourt Brace & Company items and derived items copyright © 1996 by Harcourt Brace & Company.
13.7
(a) The utility function is:

The budget constraint is:

Now,

13-10
Harcourt Brace & Company items and derived items copyright © 1996 by Harcourt Brace & Company.
Now, from (3),

For an interior solution, we must have:

So, we have:

The second condition is already incorporated in the solution of .

13-11
Harcourt Brace & Company items and derived items copyright © 1996 by Harcourt Brace & Company.
For an interior solution of
we must have,

So,

We have already assumed the second condition.


Using the values,

we get from equation (2),

and from eq. (1) we get,

So, for interior solutions of we must have:

13-12
Harcourt Brace & Company items and derived items copyright © 1996 by Harcourt Brace & Company.
(b) If , then the value function would be:

Now,

So, the value function is:

where

13-13
Harcourt Brace & Company items and derived items copyright © 1996 by Harcourt Brace & Company.
14.1
The consumer’s utility function is U(x, y) = axy + by .

Let the consumer’s fixed income be M, and fixed prices of x and y be Px and Py respectively.
Then, the first order conditions for utility maximization are:

where is the Lagrange multiplier.

From (1) and (2) we get,

Now, substituting this value of yPy in eq. (3) , we obtain,

(a1)

Similarly, solving for y gives us:

Now, the value function, V = ax*y* + by*.


By substituting values of x* and y* from eqs. (a1) & (a2) and simplifying the expression, we
get,

14-1
Harcourt Brace & Company items and derived items copyright © 1996 by Harcourt Brace & Company.
From eq. (1), we get,

Now, we turn to the expenditure minimization problem. The first order conditions for this
problem are :

where µ is the Lagrange multiplier. From (4) and (5) we get,

Substituting this value of ax into eq. (6),

Similarly, solving for x gives us :

14-2
Harcourt Brace & Company items and derived items copyright © 1996 by Harcourt Brace & Company.
Now, let’s test the three duality conditions.

The first duality condition requires xo ( U* ) = x* ( M ) and yo ( U* ) = y* ( M ).

Here,

Similarly, we can show that yo ( U* ) = y* ( M ).

The second duality condition requires . Here,

Thus, the second duality property is satisfied.

The third duality condition requires µo = 1 / *


. Here,

Thus, all three duality properties are satisfied.

14-3
Harcourt Brace & Company items and derived items copyright © 1996 by Harcourt Brace & Company.
14.2
For problem 1, the consumer’s Marshallian demand functions are equations (a1) and (a2).

The Hicksian demand functions for this problem are given by equations (b1) and (b2).

14-4
Harcourt Brace & Company items and derived items copyright © 1996 by Harcourt Brace & Company.
14.3

From definition (14.30), Roy’s identity for good x is :

From Q.1, V = ( aM + bPx )2 / 4aPxPy . So,

Now,

Similarly, for good y, Roy’s identity is:

14-5
Harcourt Brace & Company items and derived items copyright © 1996 by Harcourt Brace & Company.
14.4
From eq. (14.35), Shepard’s Lemma states that for the consumer in this problem :

From Q.1, we know that

Similarly, it can be shown that ( ∂E / ∂Py ) = yo and ( ∂E / ∂Uo ) = µo .

Thus, Shepard’s Lemma is demonstrated for the consumer in question 14.3.

14-6
Harcourt Brace & Company items and derived items copyright © 1996 by Harcourt Brace & Company.
14.5
From eq. (14.43), the Slutsky equation for the consumer in this problem is :

From Q.1, eq. (a1), we have,

From Q.1, eq. (b2), we have,

Using eqs. (2) and (3),

Now,

14-7
Harcourt Brace & Company items and derived items copyright © 1996 by Harcourt Brace & Company.
Substituting this value back into (4), we obtain,

Thus, the Slutsky equation has been demonstrated for the consumer in problem 14.1.

14-8
Harcourt Brace & Company items and derived items copyright © 1996 by Harcourt Brace & Company.
14.6
Part a.

Given is : U (x, y) = Ax x where A, , > 0.

The Lagrangian for this problem is :

The first order conditions are :

From eqs. (1) and (2), we get,

Substituting this value of y into eq. (3), we get,

14-9
Harcourt Brace & Company items and derived items copyright © 1996 by Harcourt Brace & Company.
From (4),

So, the consumer’s value function,

So, the optimal entree fee T* is the solution to the equation

where P* is the optimal price and M is consumer’s income.

14-10
Harcourt Brace & Company items and derived items copyright © 1996 by Harcourt Brace & Company.
Part b.

Given is : U (x, y) = axy + by where a, b > 0.

The Lagrangian for this problem is :

The first order conditions are :

From eqs. (1) and (2), we get,

Substituting this value of Px into (3), we get,

M - T - ((ay - bp) / a) - y = 0

aM - aT - ay - bP - ay = 0

2ay = bP + aM - aT

y* = (aM - aT + bP) / 2a

Similarly,

x* = (aM - aT - bP) / 2aP

14-11
Harcourt Brace & Company items and derived items copyright © 1996 by Harcourt Brace & Company.
So, the consumer’s value function is

So, the optimal entree fee T* is the solution to

where P* is the optimal price and M is the consumer's income.

14-12
Harcourt Brace & Company items and derived items copyright © 1996 by Harcourt Brace & Company.
Instructor’s Manual on Disk
to accompany

Mathematical Economics
by

Jeffery Baldani
James Bradfield
Robert Turner

Disk 6
( Solutions for Chapter 15, 16, 17, 18 and Appendix )
Copyright © 1996 by Harcourt Brace & Company.

All rights reserved. Subject to the restrictions hereof, permission is hereby granted until further
notice, to duplicate this diskette without alteration onto another diskette or the hard disk drive
of a computer for use in connection with a course for which Mathematical Economics, First
Edition, by Jeffery Baldani, James Bradfield and Robert Turner has been adopted, and not for
resale, provided the copies are made from this master diskette only, and provided that the
following copyright notice appears on the label of all copies in diskette form: © 1996 by
Harcourt Brace & Company. The program may not be merged into another program or modified
in any way. Copies may not be made of copies.

Problems and solutions may be displayed and may be reproduced in print form for instructional
purposes only, provided a proper copyright notice appears on the last page of each print-out.

Except as previously stated, no part of the computer program embodied in this diskette may be
reproduced or transmitted in any form or by any means, electronic or mechanical, including input
into or storage in any information system, without permission in writing from the publisher.

Produced in the United States

ISBN: 0-03-011578-7
Table of Contents

Chapter 15 Chapter 17 Chapter 18


15.1 4 17.1 37 18.1 56
15.2 5 17.2 38 – 41 18.2 57
15.3 6 17.3 42 & 43 18.3 58
15.4 7–9 17.4 44 18.4 59 & 60
15.5 10 17.5 45 18.5 61
15.6 11 17.6 46 18.6 62
15.7 12 17.7 47 & 48 18.7 63
17.8 49 18.8 64 & 65
Chapter 16 17.9 50 18.9 66
16.1 13 17.10 51 18.10 67 – 69
16.2 14 17.11 52 18.11 70
16.3 15 & 16 17.12 53 18.12 71
16.4 17 17.13 54 & 55 18.3 72 – 74
16.5 18 18.14 75 & 76
16.6 19 18.15 77
16.7 20
16.8 21 & 22 Appendix
16.9 23 A-1 78 – 80
16.10 24 & 25 A-2 81 – 84
16.11 26 & 27 A-3 85
16.12 28 A-4 86
16.13 29 – 31 A-5 87
16.14 32 – 34 A-6 88
16.15 35 & 36

Remaining chapters are on subsequent disks.


15.1
(a) Eliminate B, since it is dominated by T, then eliminate L, since it is dominated by R.
The equilibrium is (T,R) and the payoffs are (2,6).

(b) Eliminate L and R since both are dominated by C, then eliminate T and M since both
are dominated by B. The equilibrium is (B,C) and the payoffs are (6,8).

15-1
Harcourt Brace & Company items and derived items copyright © 1996 by Harcourt Brace & Company.
15.2
(a) (T,L) and (B,R) are Nash equilibria:

L R
T 4,4 2,3
B 1,3 13,9

(b) (B,C) is a Nash equilibrium (this is the same problem as 15.1(b) ):

L C R
T 3,7 2,8 3,4
M 4,3 3,9 4,2
B 5,4 6,8 3,1

(c) (T,L), (T,C), and (B,R) are all Nash equilibria:

L C R
T 8,8 9,8 3,4
M 4,9 3,7 1,2
B 5,4 3,8 6,8

(d) (M,R) and (B,L) are Nash equilibria:

L C R
T 3,7 2,8 2,4
M 4,3 1,4 4,9
B 5,4 6,3 3,4

15-2
Harcourt Brace & Company items and derived items copyright © 1996 by Harcourt Brace & Company.
15.3
(a) There are two kinds of Nash equilibria: in one,

In the other,

Proof:

Given that

If
,
then
.

Let

so both players have an incentive to increase their claims.

If

then
.

Let

so both players have an incentive to reduce their claims.

(b) There are two kinds of Nash equilibria: in one, every player i has
.

In the other, the sum of all claims equals 1.


The proof is the same as for part a.

15-3
Harcourt Brace & Company items and derived items copyright © 1996 by Harcourt Brace & Company.
15.4
(a)

so the best response function is

except that

is required.

So

15-4
Harcourt Brace & Company items and derived items copyright © 1996 by Harcourt Brace & Company.
(b)

15-5
Harcourt Brace & Company items and derived items copyright © 1996 by Harcourt Brace & Company.
(c) Assuming interior solutions,

15-6
Harcourt Brace & Company items and derived items copyright © 1996 by Harcourt Brace & Company.
15.5

15-7
Harcourt Brace & Company items and derived items copyright © 1996 by Harcourt Brace & Company.
15.6
(a)

so

(b)

(c)

15-8
Harcourt Brace & Company items and derived items copyright © 1996 by Harcourt Brace & Company.
15.7

From the text, if the payoff matrix is

then the mixed-strategy Nash equilibrium is

(a) (T,L) and (B,R) are pure strategy Nash equilibria.

The mixed-strategy Nash equilibrium is

(b) (B,R) is always a pure strategy Nash equilibrium.

If

then (T,L) is also a pure strategy Nash equilibrium.

The mixed strategy Nash equilibrium is

as long as X < 5. (If X > 5 then P* is negative or > 1.)

(c) (T,R) and (B,L) are pure strategy Nash equilibria.

The mixed-strategy Nash equilibrium is

15-9
Harcourt Brace & Company items and derived items copyright © 1996 by Harcourt Brace & Company.
16.1

(E,S) and (S,E) are pure strategy Nash equilibria.

16-1
Harcourt Brace & Company items and derived items copyright © 1996 by Harcourt Brace & Company.
16.2
(a)

(b)

16-2
Harcourt Brace & Company items and derived items copyright © 1996 by Harcourt Brace & Company.
16.3
(This is the same as problem 8.12)

For firm x,

For firm y,

16-3
Harcourt Brace & Company items and derived items copyright © 1996 by Harcourt Brace & Company.
(b) Implicitly differentiating the three FOC with respect to c,

16-4
Harcourt Brace & Company items and derived items copyright © 1996 by Harcourt Brace & Company.
16.4
(This is the same as problem 15.5)

16-5
Harcourt Brace & Company items and derived items copyright © 1996 by Harcourt Brace & Company.
16.5

by symmetry,

16-6
Harcourt Brace & Company items and derived items copyright © 1996 by Harcourt Brace & Company.
16.6
(a)

(b)

16-7
Harcourt Brace & Company items and derived items copyright © 1996 by Harcourt Brace & Company.
16.7
(a)

can never be a Nash equilibrium since at least one firm could earn greater profit by
cutting price.

For any
,

firm 2 has no incentive to change,

but firm 1 always has an incentive to increase price by an additional

The (approximate) Nash equilibrium is


and

since firm 1 could at best get an infinitesimal improvement in profit.

(b) If prices are measured in pennies, the Nash equilibria are any prices for which

and .

But all prices

are weakly dominated.

So if we eliminate those, the remaining equilibrium is


and .

16-8
Harcourt Brace & Company items and derived items copyright © 1996 by Harcourt Brace & Company.
16.8
The solutions for prices and quantities in general are (note that < 1 and the problem is
symmetric)

(a)

16-9
Harcourt Brace & Company items and derived items copyright © 1996 by Harcourt Brace & Company.
(b)

(c)

16-10
Harcourt Brace & Company items and derived items copyright © 1996 by Harcourt Brace & Company.
16.9
A strategy consists of two simultaneous elements: an entry decision and a price.
Let demand be

Q = Q(P) where .
_
Define P

as the price such that a monopolist would break even:

_
^
Define P > P

as the price at which 2 duopolists would break even:

There are two possible equilibria:


^
1. Both enter: This can only be an equilibrium if the equilibrium price P* ≥ P yet if this
were true either firm would have an incentive to change strategy since by cutting price it
could capture the entire market and earn higher profit. Thus there is no equilibrium when
both enter.
_
2. Only one firm enters: (a) If the entering firm charges P > P this isn't a Nash
equilibrium since the other firm would want to enter, charge a slightly lower price, and
_
earn positive profit; (b) If the entering firm charges P the other firm will not enter; but
given that the other firm doesn't enter, the firm that does enter must have an equilibrium
_
price equal to the monopoly price, which is greater than P . This is a contradiction, so
_
P = P is not a Nash equilibrium.

Thus there is no pure strategy Nash equilibrium for this game.

16-11
Harcourt Brace & Company items and derived items copyright © 1996 by Harcourt Brace & Company.
16.10
.

By symmetry, , so

16-12
Harcourt Brace & Company items and derived items copyright © 1996 by Harcourt Brace & Company.
16-13
Harcourt Brace & Company items and derived items copyright © 1996 by Harcourt Brace & Company.
16.11
.

To get the Nash equilibrium, solve the FOC


.

Let be the Nash equilibrium and


.

Then
.

To get the social optimum, maximize

by solving the FOC


.

^
Let X by the social optimum, so

16-14
Harcourt Brace & Company items and derived items copyright © 1996 by Harcourt Brace & Company.
Proof (by contradiction) that

Suppose that
.

Then

which is a contradiction.

So
.

16-15
Harcourt Brace & Company items and derived items copyright © 1996 by Harcourt Brace & Company.
16.12
so the Nash equilibrium comes from

: .

Note that the SOC requires a < 1.

The social optimum comes from maximizing

so
.

The Nash equilibrium only requires that

Any distribution (not necessarily symmetric) of the firms' outputs that satisfies

is a Nash equilibrium.

15-16
Harcourt Brace & Company items and derived items copyright © 1996 by Harcourt Brace & Company.
16.13
(a) Let be the location for seller i. For player 1 the payoff function is:

where qi depends on x1 and x2

Specifically,

The Nash equilibrium is

Proof that there is no incentive to change strategy:

15-17
Harcourt Brace & Company items and derived items copyright © 1996 by Harcourt Brace & Company.
(b) Let the three vendors' location choices be x1 , x2 , and x3

There are three possible forms for the Nash equilibrium:

(i)

(ii)

(iii)

All other forms are analogous to these since the firms can be ordered arbitrarily. If none of
these are pure strategy Nash equilibria then there are no pure strategy Nash equilibria.

(i) If
,
then

But either

will yield a payoff

so there are no Nash equilibria of this form.

(ii) If

then

yields a higher Π1
If

then

yields a higher Π2

15-18
Harcourt Brace & Company items and derived items copyright © 1996 by Harcourt Brace & Company.
If

the only possible equilibrium for vendor 1 is

But if

yields a higher Π2

So there are no Nash equilibria of this form.

(iii) If

then for players 1 and 3 to be in equilibrium they must be as close as possible to player 2, so

This leads to
,

but then player 2 has an incentive to change since either

So there are no Nash equilibria of this form.

15-19
Harcourt Brace & Company items and derived items copyright © 1996 by Harcourt Brace & Company.
16.14
Let . The demand equations are

(a)

(b) Firm x faces the constraint that

The Lagrangian for firm x is

with FOC

15-20
Harcourt Brace & Company items and derived items copyright © 1996 by Harcourt Brace & Company.
The FOC for firm y's unconstrained profit-maximization problem is

(c) In matrix form, the FOC are

15-21
Harcourt Brace & Company items and derived items copyright © 1996 by Harcourt Brace & Company.
Since
.

(d) Since dy = - dx, dn = 0.

So

Thus when x increases and y decreases by the same amount, the market price rises. Firm x
would like to price discriminate, charging a monopoly price at home and a lower price in the
duopoly market. Since it can't, it lowers price at home and raises the price for exports. The
mix of the two depends on which market is bigger. When the home market is bigger, price
equalization is achieved largely through a higher export price.

15-22
Harcourt Brace & Company items and derived items copyright © 1996 by Harcourt Brace & Company.
16.15

(a)

so the response functions are

(b)

15-23
Harcourt Brace & Company items and derived items copyright © 1996 by Harcourt Brace & Company.
(c)

So .

15-24
Harcourt Brace & Company items and derived items copyright © 1996 by Harcourt Brace & Company.
17.1
(a) Player 1 has an information set at the initial node. Player 2 has two singleton
information sets: one following L, one following R. There are two subgames: one
after R, one after fL. Yes, perfect information.

(b) Player 1 has two wingleton informations sets: one at the initial node, one at the node
following L,U. Player 2 has two singleton information sets: one following L, one
following R. There are 3 subgames, starting at each of player 2's singleton
information sets and at player 1's second information set. Yes, perfect information.

(c) Each of player 1's nodes is a singleton information set. Player 2 has a singleton
information set and an information set with two nodes. There are 3 subgames. 2 start
at player 1's information sets and one starts at player 2's singleton information set.
No, imperfect information.

(d) All information sets are singletons (each player has two information sets). There are 5
subgames: 2 at player 2's nodes, 2 at player 3's nodes, and 1 at player 1's second node.
Yes, perfect information.

(e) There is a singleton information set for player 1, 2 singleton information sets for
player 2, and 1 doubleton information set for player 3. There are 2 subgames, one
starting at each of player 2's nodes. No, imperfect information.

17-1
Harcourt Brace & Company items and derived items copyright © 1996 by Harcourt Brace & Company.
17.2
(a) (i) Strategy sets: Player 1 {L,C,R}
Player 2 {(U,U,U), (U,D,U), (U,U,D), (U,D,D), (D,U,U), (D,D,U),
(D,U,D), (D,D,D)} where (i,j,k) represent responses to player 1's choices of
L,C, and R.

(ii) U,U,U U,D,U U,U,D U,D,D D,U,U D,D,U D,U,D D,D,D


L 10,4 10,4 10,4 10,4 2,6 2,6 2,6 2,6
C 3,10 3,10 3,10 3,10 3,10 3,10 3,10 3,10
R 10,4 10,4 2,3 2,3 10,4 10,4 2,3 2,3
Nash equilibrium strategies:

C D,U,D
C D,D,D
R U,U,U
R U,D,U
R D,U,U
R D,D,U

(iii) Subgame perfection requires that player 2 choose D in response to L and U in


response to R. Thus, subgame perfect strategies for player 2 take the form
(D,?,U). The subgame perfect Nash equilibria are

R D,U,U
R D,D,U

(b) (i) Strategy sets: Player 1 {L,R}


Player 2 {(U,U), (U,M), (U,D), (D,D), (D,M), (D,U), (M,M), (M,U), (M,D)}

17-2
Harcourt Brace & Company items and derived items copyright © 1996 by Harcourt Brace & Company.
(ii) U,U U,M U,D D,D D,M D,U M,M M,U M,D
L 2,3 2,3 2,3 2,6 2,6 2,4 2,4 2,4 2,4
R 1,1 3,3 1,2 1,2 3,3 1,1 3,3 1,1 1,2
Nash equilibrium strategies are

L D,D
L D,U
R U,M
R D,M
R M,M

(iii) Subgame perfection requires that player 2's response to (L,R) be (D,M) so the only
subgame perfect Nash equilibrium is R, (D,M).

(c) (i) Strategy sets: Player 1 {L,C,R}


Player 2 {(U,U,U), (U,D,U), (U,U,D), (U,D,D), (D,U,U), (D,D,U),
(D,U,D), (D,D,D)} where (i,j,k) represent responses to player 1's choices of
L,C, and R.

(ii) U,U,U U,D,U U,U,D U,D,D D,U,U D,D,U D,U,D D,D,D


L 4,6 4,6 4,6 4,6 4,2 4,2 4,2 4,2
C 0,6 8,5 0,6 8,5 0,6 8,5 0,6 8,5
R 4,3 4,3 5,4 5,4 4,3 4,3 5,4 5,4
Nash equilibrium strategies:

L U,U,U
R U,U,D
R D,U,D

17-3
Harcourt Brace & Company items and derived items copyright © 1996 by Harcourt Brace & Company.
(iii) Subgame perfection requires that the responses to L,C, and R must be (U,U,D) so
the only subgame perfect Nash equilibrium is R, (U,U,D).

(d) (i) Strategies for player 2 (responses to L and R) are

Each strategy for player 1 is an initial move followed by a set of responses to each of
player 2's strategies:

Player 1 has 32 total strategies

(ii) U,U D,U D,D U,D


8,6 6,6 6,6 8,6
8,6 6,6 6,6 3,5
3,5 6,6 6,6 8,6
3,5 6,6 6,6 3,5
9,6 9,6 3,7 3,7
9,6 8,5 3,7 3,7
8,5 9,6 3,7 3,7
8,5 8,5 3,7 3,7
where X stands for (payoff-irrelevant) responses to D moves

17-4
Harcourt Brace & Company items and derived items copyright © 1996 by Harcourt Brace & Company.
The Nash equilibrium strategies are

Since each X,X pair represents 4 combinations, there are 24 Nash equilibrium strategies.

(iii) is a dominant strategy for player 1 in the final subgames. Thus, in the
subgame following L, player 2 is indifferent between U and D. In the subgame
following R, player 2 will choose D. Thus U,D and D,D are subgame perfect
strategies for player 2. Given this, player 1 will never choose R. Thus the
subgame perfect Nash equilibria are

There are 8 subgame perfect Nash equilibria.

17-5
Harcourt Brace & Company items and derived items copyright © 1996 by Harcourt Brace & Company.
17.3
(a) Following L, player 2's best response is D. Following R, player 2's best response is
U. Given that player 2 will play strategy (D,U), player 1's best choice is R. So the
subgame perfect Nash equilibrium is for player 1 to play R and player 2 to play
(D,U).

(b) At player 1's second decision point the best response is B. Following L, player 2's
best response is D. Following R, player 2's best response is U. Given that player 2
will play strategy (D,U), player 1 is indifferent between L and R. Thus player 1's T -
B choice is irrelevant. The subgame perfect Nash equilibria are L, (D,U) and R,
(D,U).

(c) D is a dominant action in both of player 2's information sets. Thus (D,D) is player 2's
equilibrium strategy. Given (D,D) for player 2, player 1 will choose T if Nature
chooses L and player 1 will choose B if Nature chooses R. The subgame perfect Nash
equilibrium is (T,B), (D,D).

(d) Set up the following stages to discuss the problem:


Stage 1: player 1 chooses L or R
Stage 2a: player 2 chooses U or D
Stage 2b: player 3 chooses M or S
Stage 3a: player 3 chooses M or S
Stage 3b: player 2 chooses U or D
Stage 4: player 1 chooses

Backwards induction for the game that includes stages 1, 2a, and 3a:
In stage 3a, player 3 chooses S; in stage 2a, player 2 chooses U; in stage 1, player 1
chooses L. The resulting sequence of plays is L,U,S and the payoffs are (1,2,4).

17-6
Harcourt Brace & Company items and derived items copyright © 1996 by Harcourt Brace & Company.
Backwards induction for the game that includes stages 1, 2b, 3b, and 4:
In stage 4, player 1 chooses ; in stage 3b, player 2 chooses U; in stage 2b, player 3
chooses M; in stage 1, player 1 chooses R. The resulting sequence of plays is R,M
and the payoffs are (2,1,2).

Thus the subgame perfect Nash equilibrium is for player 1 to play R and player 3 to
play M, resulting in payoffs of (2,1,2).

(e) In the information set for player 3, M is a dominant choice. On the right side, player
2 is indifferent between U and D. On the left side, player 2 picks U. If player 1
picks L, then player 2 picks U, with payoffs (2,6,8). If player 1 picks R, player 2
might pick U, followed by player 3 choosing M, resulting in payoffs (7,5,2), or player
2 might pick D, followed by player 3 choosing M, resulting in payoffs (7,5,3).
So the subgame perfect Nash equilibria are
R,U,M, giving payoffs (7,5,2)
and R,D,M, giving payoffs (7,5,3).

17-7
Harcourt Brace & Company items and derived items copyright © 1996 by Harcourt Brace & Company.
17.4
(a) see Figure 17.6

(b) see Figure 17.7

(c) like Figure 17.10 with an information set connecting firm 1's decision nodes

(d) An initial move by Nature with one branch followed by the tree for game (b) and the
other branch followed by the tree for game (c)

(e) The high-demand game matrix is

Each firm has a dominant strategy: PL is best with either a high or low demand. This is a
prisoners' dilemma and the equilibrium is (PL , PL ) for all of the game sequences in parts
(a) through (d).

17-8
Harcourt Brace & Company items and derived items copyright © 1996 by Harcourt Brace & Company.
17.5
The strategy for player 1 is a choice s1 and the strategy for player 2 is a response function
. The Nash equilibrium is any s*1 such that

and

such that

Explanation: This ensures that player 1 has no incentive to change s1 away from the
equilibrium value s*1 . Player 2's response function is optimal given the actual choice of s*1.

The subgame perfect Nash equilibrium is found by seeing that

is the only subgame perfect choice for player 2, so the best choice by player 1 is
.

17-9
Harcourt Brace & Company items and derived items copyright © 1996 by Harcourt Brace & Company.
17.6
(a) so and .

(b) the payoffs are

, so

17-10
Harcourt Brace & Company items and derived items copyright © 1996 by Harcourt Brace & Company.
17.7
(a) so so

17-11
Harcourt Brace & Company items and derived items copyright © 1996 by Harcourt Brace & Company.
(b) Note that R2 ( x1 ) and R3 ( x1, x2 ) do not depend directly on c1.

Thus changes in do not have any effect on the strategies of players 2 and 3.

17-12
Harcourt Brace & Company items and derived items copyright © 1996 by Harcourt Brace & Company.
17.8
In the second stage,

so the second-stage solutions are

In the first stage,

17-13
Harcourt Brace & Company items and derived items copyright © 1996 by Harcourt Brace & Company.
17.9
In the second stage,

In the first stage,

17-14
Harcourt Brace & Company items and derived items copyright © 1996 by Harcourt Brace & Company.
17.10
In the second stage, if

this is a prisoners' dilemma and the subgame equilibrium is H,H with payoffs 1,1.

If

then it is no longer a prisoners' dilemma, but the equilibrium is still H,H.

If

then the equilibrium is L,L with payoffs 12,12.

In the first stage,


player 2

1,1 1,-2 1,-4


player 1 -2,1 9, 9 9, 7
-4,1 7, 9 7, 7

are both first-stage equilibria.

So the subgame-perfect Nash equilibria are

, H,H
and
, L,L.

17-15
Harcourt Brace & Company items and derived items copyright © 1996 by Harcourt Brace & Company.
17.11
(a) (S,E) and (E,S) are pure strategy equilibria.

(b) Player 1 observes both player 1's and player 2's first-round decisions.
Player 1's second-round decision can be contingent on both first-round decisions.
A strategy for player 1 is a first-round decision followed by a contingent second-round
decision:
Player 2's first-round choice
first-round E S
Player 1's E E E
strategies E S E
E E S
E S S
S E E
S S E
S E S
S S S

Strategy combinations that are subgame perfect and yield positive payoffs for both players
are those in which one player enters in the first round and stays out in the second round,
while the other player stays out in the first round and enters in the second round. Some
examples (there are others) are

Player 1 Player 2
E S S S E E
E E S S E E
E E S S E S

17-16
Harcourt Brace & Company items and derived items copyright © 1996 by Harcourt Brace & Company.
17.12

From equation (17.29), the critical value of with the shorter time lag is .

With the two-period lag, we have a higher critical value of :

17-17
Harcourt Brace & Company items and derived items copyright © 1996 by Harcourt Brace & Company.
17.13
(a)

by symmetry,

(b)

by symmetry,

(c) the trigger strategy is

(d)

17-18
Harcourt Brace & Company items and derived items copyright © 1996 by Harcourt Brace & Company.
(e)

The trigger strategy is a Nash equilibrium if .

17-19
Harcourt Brace & Company items and derived items copyright © 1996 by Harcourt Brace & Company.
18.1

At t = 2, y accepts if
.

At t = 1, x accepts if
.

At t = 0, y accepts if
.

So the equilibrium is

18-1
Harcourt Brace & Company items and derived items copyright © 1996 by Harcourt Brace & Company.
18.2

At t = 1, x accepts if
.

At t = 0, y accepts if
.

So the equilibrium is

In the common discount factor case,


. Let .

Suppose that player x is less "impatient" (discounts less) than player y.

Then and .

The less impatient player earns a higher payoff.

18-2
Harcourt Brace & Company items and derived items copyright © 1996 by Harcourt Brace & Company.
18.3
Second-stage equilibria: if there are two firms,

if there is one firm, price equals the monopoly price

and .

First-stage equilibrium: Firm 1 enters, firm 2 stays out,

18-3
Harcourt Brace & Company items and derived items copyright © 1996 by Harcourt Brace & Company.
18.4
(a) . In the second stage,

18-4
Harcourt Brace & Company items and derived items copyright © 1996 by Harcourt Brace & Company.
(b) so

In the symmetric model, , so

There is a tariff.

18-5
Harcourt Brace & Company items and derived items copyright © 1996 by Harcourt Brace & Company.
18.5
From equation (18.10), with sy = 0 we get

From equation (18.12), with sy = 0 we get

with this is identical to the Stackelberg leadership solution in equation (18.25).

The government of x sets the subsidy to manipulate to values that maximize x's profit.

Thus it plays the role of a leader that is the same as the Stackelberg leadership role.

18-6
Harcourt Brace & Company items and derived items copyright © 1996 by Harcourt Brace & Company.
18.6
(a) and

. But in this example, c = 0.

(b)

which is the monopoly price

18-7
Harcourt Brace & Company items and derived items copyright © 1996 by Harcourt Brace & Company.
18.7
(a)

(b)

(c)

The tariff hurts consumers but transfers money from foreign profits to domestic government

revenue. As n increases the market becomes more competitive, foreign firms earn less profit,

and there is less of an incentive (given the harm to consumers) to tax imports.

18-8
Harcourt Brace & Company items and derived items copyright © 1996 by Harcourt Brace & Company.
18.8

so the response function


.
Since
.

18-9
Harcourt Brace & Company items and derived items copyright © 1996 by Harcourt Brace & Company.
(b)

18-10
Harcourt Brace & Company items and derived items copyright © 1996 by Harcourt Brace & Company.
18.9

so the response function is


.

The sequential game equilibrium is the same as the simultaneous game equilibrium of
Chapter 16.

18-11
Harcourt Brace & Company items and derived items copyright © 1996 by Harcourt Brace & Company.
18.10
(i) Firm 2's choice: Suppose firm 2 enters. Its profit is
.

Since q1 is already chosen, the profit-maximizing q2 is derived from

Firm 2's profit, conditional on q1 is

Firm 2 will stay out if

Define
.

(ii) Firm 1's choice:

(a) If entry is to occur, firm 1's best output choice is the Stackelberg leader output (same
as the monopoly output)
.

Then, with entry,


.

Note, however, that if the fixed cost for firm 2 is large enough, then the best response

to is for firm 2 to stay out of the market. This occurs when

18-12
Harcourt Brace & Company items and derived items copyright © 1996 by Harcourt Brace & Company.
(b) Firm 1 can also choose to produce ^q (assuming entry would occur if q1 = q1L )

in order to keep firm 2 out of the market. Since


,

(c) Firm 1's decision (assuming entry would occur when q1 = q1L = a / 2 ):

Firm 1 will choose ^q and prevent entry by firm 2 if

(the positive root is discarded because for f that large, firm 2 would not

enter when q1 = q1L )

18-13
Harcourt Brace & Company items and derived items copyright © 1996 by Harcourt Brace & Company.
(iii) Equilibrium:

Case I:

firm 1 chooses

firm 2 enters with

Case II:

firm 1 chooses

firm 2 stays out

Case III:

firm 1 chooses the monopoly output

firm 2 stays out

18-14
Harcourt Brace & Company items and derived items copyright © 1996 by Harcourt Brace & Company.
18.11
Second Stage Solution:

In the first stage firm 1 maximizes

The first order condition yields:

so that the leader firm’s output does not depend on the number of followers

Substituting the output solution into the leader’s profit function gives:

so that as the number of followers increases, profits decrease.

18-15
Harcourt Brace & Company items and derived items copyright © 1996 by Harcourt Brace & Company.
18.12
(a)

(b) The simultaneous game has a symmetric equilibrium,


,

Both firms earn higher profits in the sequential game, but the profit improvement is larger for
firm 2 (the follower)

18-16
Harcourt Brace & Company items and derived items copyright © 1996 by Harcourt Brace & Company.
18.13
The cooperative equilibrium is

The Nash equilibrium is

(a)

18-17
Harcourt Brace & Company items and derived items copyright © 1996 by Harcourt Brace & Company.
(b) so

Thus

Since
,

a low r means a high .

18-18
Harcourt Brace & Company items and derived items copyright © 1996 by Harcourt Brace & Company.
(c) If

If

When n reaches a critical level, firms defect to the Nash equilibrium.

18-19
Harcourt Brace & Company items and derived items copyright © 1996 by Harcourt Brace & Company.
18.14
(a) See problem 16.7 for explanation. Let the market demand be Q = Q (P)

Then the Nash equilibrium is

(b) The demand equation gives

so and .

The trigger strategy requires both firms to cooperate; the defection strategy for each firm
is to charge and sell the entire market quantity, .

The trigger strategy works for firm 2 if


.

The trigger strategy works for firm 1 if


or

18-20
Harcourt Brace & Company items and derived items copyright © 1996 by Harcourt Brace & Company.
So the trigger strategy works for

This range exists for some but not all values of and demand and cost functions.

If the range exists then the upper limit is unaffected by changes in c, but the lower limit
increases with c, since
.

The level of s needed to satisfy the requirement that firm 1 cooperates is increasing in c.
This is because when c increases, the Nash equilibrium is more profitable for firm 1.

18-21
Harcourt Brace & Company items and derived items copyright © 1996 by Harcourt Brace & Company.
18.15

(a) is the Nash equilibrium.


.

(b) , .

The trigger strategy works when , the number of possible defection periods, is
sufficiently low.

(Since 0 < δ < 1, δτ gets larger when is lower.)

18-22
Harcourt Brace & Company items and derived items copyright © 1996 by Harcourt Brace & Company.
A.1
(a)

(b)

(c)

(d)

(e)

A-1
Harcourt Brace & Company items and derived items copyright © 1996 by Harcourt Brace & Company.
(f)

(g)

(h)

(i)

(j)

A-2
Harcourt Brace & Company items and derived items copyright © 1996 by Harcourt Brace & Company.
(k)

(l)

A-3
Harcourt Brace & Company items and derived items copyright © 1996 by Harcourt Brace & Company.
A.2
(a)

(b)

(c)

A-4
Harcourt Brace & Company items and derived items copyright © 1996 by Harcourt Brace & Company.
(d)

(e)

A-5
Harcourt Brace & Company items and derived items copyright © 1996 by Harcourt Brace & Company.
(f)

(g)

A-6
Harcourt Brace & Company items and derived items copyright © 1996 by Harcourt Brace & Company.
(h)

A-7
Harcourt Brace & Company items and derived items copyright © 1996 by Harcourt Brace & Company.
A.3
(a)

so is convex

(b)

so is concave

(c)

so is concave

(d)

so is convex

(e)

so is convex if a > 1; and concave if a < 1

(f)

so is convex

A-8
Harcourt Brace & Company items and derived items copyright © 1996 by Harcourt Brace & Company.
A.4
(a)

(b)

(c)

(d)

(e)

A-9
Harcourt Brace & Company items and derived items copyright © 1996 by Harcourt Brace & Company.
A.5
(a)

(b)

(c)

(d)

(e)

A-10
Harcourt Brace & Company items and derived items copyright © 1996 by Harcourt Brace & Company.
A.6
(a)

(b)

(c)

(d)

(e)

A-11
Harcourt Brace & Company items and derived items copyright © 1996 by Harcourt Brace & Company.

You might also like