You are on page 1of 5

This article was downloaded by: [University of Guelph]

On: 30 May 2012, At: 08:53


Publisher: Routledge
Informa Ltd Registered in England and Wales Registered Number: 1072954 Registered office: Mortimer House,
37-41 Mortimer Street, London W1T 3JH, UK

Applied Economics Letters


Publication details, including instructions for authors and subscription information:
http://www.tandfonline.com/loi/rael20

Determinants of the long-run growth rate of


Bangladesh
a a
B. Bhaskara Rao & Gazi Hassan
a
School of Economics and Finance, University of Western Sydney, Sydney, Australia

Available online: 13 Jan 2011

To cite this article: B. Bhaskara Rao & Gazi Hassan (2011): Determinants of the long-run growth rate of Bangladesh, Applied
Economics Letters, 18:7, 655-658

To link to this article: http://dx.doi.org/10.1080/13504851003800760

PLEASE SCROLL DOWN FOR ARTICLE

Full terms and conditions of use: http://www.tandfonline.com/page/terms-and-conditions

This article may be used for research, teaching, and private study purposes. Any substantial or systematic
reproduction, redistribution, reselling, loan, sub-licensing, systematic supply, or distribution in any form to
anyone is expressly forbidden.

The publisher does not give any warranty express or implied or make any representation that the contents
will be complete or accurate or up to date. The accuracy of any instructions, formulae, and drug doses should
be independently verified with primary sources. The publisher shall not be liable for any loss, actions, claims,
proceedings, demand, or costs or damages whatsoever or howsoever caused arising directly or indirectly in
connection with or arising out of the use of this material.
Applied Economics Letters, 2011, 18, 655–658

Determinants of the long-run


growth rate of Bangladesh
B. Bhaskara Rao and Gazi Hassan*
School of Economics and Finance, University of Western Sydney, Sydney,
Australia

This article estimates Total Factor Productivity (TFP) for Bangladesh and
analyses its key determinants. According to the Solow (1956) growth model,
long-run growth rate equals TFP. Estimated b-coefficients show that trade
Downloaded by [University of Guelph] at 08:53 30 May 2012

openness, foreign direct investment and development of financial sector


increase TFP.

I. Introduction where Y = output, A = stock of knowledge, K = stock


of capital, H = an index of human capital formation
This article analyses some key determinants of the long- through education and L = employment. Unit root
run growth rate of Bangladesh. Our framework uses tests for these variables did not yield unequivocal
theoretical insights from the Solow (1956) growth results. Although Y and (H · L) are found to be I(1)
model and the growth accounting framework in Solow in levels by the Augmented Dickey–Fuller (ADF) and
(1957). Our empirical methodology is based on the Kwiatkowski–Phillips–Schmidt–Shin (KPSS) tests, K
extensions to these works by Mankiw et al. (1992) and is found to be I(1) by only the Elliot, Rothenberg and
Senhadji (2000). Empirical results for Bangladesh are Stock (ERS) point optimal test. As there is some doubt
estimated for the period 1970 to 2007. on the order of integration of these variables, we shall
In Section II a production function for Bangladesh is use the ARDL approach, based on the bounds test, for
estimated. Using the estimated factor elasticities, a estimation. It is well known that the bounds test does
growth-accounting exercise is conducted next to esti- not require pretesting of the variables and is popular in
mate Total Factor Productivity (TFP). In Section III many applications. The implication is that this techni-
the Autoregressive Distributed Lag (ARDL) approach que can be used if the variables are I(0) and/or I(1).
is used to estimate the long-run relationship between Using this approach we found that Y, L · H and K are
TFP and its key determinants. Policy implications and cointegrated. The computed test statistic F(2, 29) =
conclusions are discussed in Section IV. 5.456 exceeds the upper bound critical value of 4.855
at the 5% level and the null of no cointegration is
rejected. The estimated value of a, with the t-ratio in
II. The Production Function and TFP brackets, is 0.468 (15.30) and is highly significant.1
Using this value, TFP is estimated as follows:
The following specification of the human capital aug-
mented Cobb–Douglas production function with con- TFP ;  ln Y  0:468 ln K
ð2Þ
stant returns to scale is used. A similar function is also  ð1  0:468Þð ln H þ  ln LÞ
used by Senhadji (2000).
The average TFP before 1990 was -0.6% and this has
Yt ¼ At Kta ðHt · Lt Þð1aÞ ð1Þ increased to near 0 during 2000 to 2007. During the

*Corresponding author. E-mail: gazi.hassan@gmail.com


1
Details of the unit root and bounds test results are not reported to conserve space and may be obtained from us. Definitions of
the variables and data sources can also be obtained from us. Due to the limited space these are not included.

Applied Economics Letters ISSN 1350–4851 print/ISSN 1466–4291 online # 2011 Taylor & Francis 655
http://www.informaworld.com
DOI: 10.1080/13504851003800760
656 B. B. Rao and G. Hassan
2000s, per capita income grew at an average rate of 2.5%. positive or negative effects, (8) a dummy variable to
This was due to factor accumulation, which is difficult to capture the effects of reforms since the late 1980s
sustain over longer periods because of negligible TFP. To (DUM90, +) and (9) the rate of inflation (PRAT, -).
double the per capita income from US$428 in 2007 in The expected signs for these variables are shown in
about 15 years, it is necessary to increase the per capita parentheses. Definitions of the variables and sources of
income growth rate at least to 4.5%. A policy option is to data may be obtained from the authors.
increase TFP to 2.5% and also to ensure that factor Our aim is to estimate a cointegrating equation, if it
accumulation contributes the balance of 2%.2 exists, to estimate the long-run relationship between TFP
and its key determinants. When these variables are tested
for unit roots, TFP and PRAT are found to be stationary
III. Determinants of TFP whereas all other variables are nonstationary. Instead of
conducting a variety of unit root tests with many alter-
Many empirical works on growth claim that their spe- native options, which seems to have become currently
cifications are based on one or another endogenous prolific and perhaps a less meaningful activity, we shall
growth model. In our view, the specifications in most use the ARDL approach for cointegration, which, as
of these works are arbitrary and their results need to be noted earlier, does not need pretesting of the variables.
interpreted cautiously. Commenting on the arbitrary Furthermore, we shall use the standardized variables to
nature of specifications, Easterly et al. (2004) have estimate the b-coefficients for easy comparisons of the
Downloaded by [University of Guelph] at 08:53 30 May 2012

observed that ‘This literature has the usual limitations relative contribution of these variables to TFP. With only
of choosing a specification without clear guidance from 38 observations it is not possible to determine the optimal
theory, which often means there are more plausible lag order for Vector Autoregression (VAR) with 10 vari-
specifications than there are data points in the sample.’ ables even if we use an initial lag order of 2. Therefore, we
Consequently, Durlauf et al. (2005) have found that have used only three crucial ratios namely, FDIRAT,
the number of potential TFP improving variables in GRAT and TRAT, starting with five lags, to determine
various empirical works is as many as 145. Therefore, the order of VAR. The Schwarz Bayesian Criterion
it is hard to select a handful of key determinants of TFP (SBIC) indicated that a second-order VAR is optimal.3
from such a large list of variables. Nevertheless, because We also made a small change to the sequence of four
data on country-specific time series are limited, we can steps in the ARDL approach to cointegration. First, the
select only a few key determinants of TFP. We selected optimal order of the unrestricted VAR is selected. Second,
nine such potential variables that affect TFP. These using this order, a cointegration test is conducted. Third,
are the ratios to Gross Domestic Product (GDP) of if there is cointegration, the long-run cointegrating coeffi-
(1) foreign direct investment (FDIRAT, +), (2) overseas cients are estimated with the bounds test and finally, with
development aid (ODARAT, +), (3) M2 (M2RAT, +) the lagged Error Correction Term (ECT) and an ARDL
as a proxy for development of the financial sector, specification, the final dynamic structure for the changes
(4) remittances by emigrant workers (REMRAT, ) in the dependent variable is estimated. Given that we have
which is a significant proportion to GDP in Bangladesh, nine potential variables to explain TFP it is convenient to
(5) trade openness (TRAT, +) proxied with the ratio of follow steps 1 and 3 to start with and conduct the coin-
imports plus exports to GDP and (6) current government tegration test with only the significant variables found in
expenditure (GRAT, -). Three other explanatory vari- step 3. Using a second-order VAR, the estimated equa-
ables are (7) a time trend (T, ) to capture the effects of tion in step 3, after deleting the insignificant variables one
other trended but ignored variables which may have at a time, is as follows4:

TFPz ¼1:828  0:164T þ 0:776DUM90  0:913GRATz  0:755PRATz


ð3:24Þ ð4:68Þ ð12:37Þ ð3:49Þ ð4:61Þ
ð3Þ
þ 0:462TRATz þ 0:217FDIRATz þ 0:402M2RATz
ð3:42Þ ð2:08Þ ð1:78Þ

2
This is a suggested option, which we think is a pragmatic option. However, we think that to increase TFP to a higher level some
difficult and large changes in policy measures are necessary.
3
Akaike’s Information Criteria (AIC) indicated a higher order for VAR but this is not a pragmatic option. Our procedure for
the optimal lag is perhaps better than the arbitrary selection of one or two periods in many works citing data limitations as the
reason.
4
First, we delete a variable with the smallest t-ratio and below the 5% critical value. The equation is reestimated and another
insignificant variable is removed. This procedure is continued until all the retained coefficients are significant.
Determinants of TFP in Bangladesh 657
Standardized variables are denoted with the Z sector, trade openness, foreign direct investment, cur-
subscript. t-Ratios are below the coefficients in the rent government expenditure and inflation.
brackets. These estimates are impressive and all the
coefficients have the expected signs and are significant IV. Policy Implications and Conclusion
at the conventional levels of 5 or 10%. The positive
and significant coefficient for DUM90 implies that In this article we found some key determinants of TFP
reforms in Bangladesh have enhanced TFP. The nega- for Bangladesh. The ratios to GDP of trade openness,
tive effects of GRAT and PRAT are larger in absolute foreign direct investment and progress in the financial
value than the positive effects of TRAT, M2RAT and sector have significant positive effects. Economic
FDIRAT. reforms from 1990 have also had a significant positive
Negative and significant coefficient for trend effect. Government current expenditure and inflation
indicates that it is necessary to implement policies rate have relatively large negative effects on TFP.
to improve the overall efficiency in Bangladesh. Although the average rate of growth of per capita
Although some of these negative TFP effects can be output during 2000 to 2007 was 2.5%, the average
offset by increasing the ratios with positive coeffi- TFP was negligible. Therefore, it is not possible to
cients, decreasing the negative effects is more amen- sustain this growth rate in the long run because it is
able to quickly respond to policy changes. For entirely because of factor accumulation. To increase
example, it may be relatively quick to reduce govern-
Downloaded by [University of Guelph] at 08:53 30 May 2012

this growth rate to 4.5% to double the per capita


ment expenditure and inflation rate than to increase income in 15 years, it is necessary to increase TFP to
foreign direct investment or speed up the progress of 2.5% and maintain the contribution of factor accu-
the financial sector. mulation to growth by 2%.
We reestimated Equation 3 by allowing for the How can this be achieved? Alternative scenarios are
negative effects of a major natural calamity during possible but we opt for the following. If GRAT and
2004 by adding an additional dummy DUM04 to cap- PRAT can be decreased by 10% from their 2000 to
ture this effect. These estimates are as follows: 2007 averages and TRAT, FDIRAT and M2RAT can

TFPz ¼ 3:019  0:163T þ 0:785DUM90  0:662DUM04  0:822GRATz


ð5:61Þ ð5:43Þ ð4:067Þ ð2:76Þ ð3:67Þ
ð4Þ
 0:728PRATz þ 0:383TRATz þ 0:228FDIRATz þ 0:490M2RATz
ð5:20Þ ð3:25Þ ð2:53Þ ð2:45Þ

Addition of this dummy made only marginal changes be increased by 7.5% from their averages, TFP can be
to the estimated coefficients but the coefficient of increased to 2.5% to sustain growth of per capita
M2RAT has increased and become significant at the income at 2.5%. If the three variables, TRAT,
5% level. This is not unexpected because various sec- FDIRAT and M2RAT, are increased by another per-
tors try to improve efficiency to meet emergency needs centage point, TFP will be 3%. Factor accumulation
and the financial sector might have responded posi- should fill the gap between these rates and the target
tively because of the large amounts of aid money it 4.5% per capita growth because increase of TFP
might have received from the emigrant workers and further may require harsher measures to reduce gov-
international agencies. ernment expenditure and anti-inflation policies.
We shall use the variables in Equation 4 with the These policies to increase TFP can be implemented
two dummy variables and a second-order VAR for in the short to medium terms. Furthermore, their
testing cointegration with the bounds test. The com- transitional growth effects, ignored in this short arti-
puted test statistic, after adding the relevant one- cle, will also be significant. Hopefully our framework
period lagged level variables, is F(6, 13) = 24.827 and results will also interest policy makers of other
and exceeds the upper bound value of 4.088 at the developing countries.
5% level. Therefore, the null of no cointegration can
be rejected and it may be concluded that in
Bangladesh there is a robust long-run relationship References
between TFP (which is also its steady-state growth Durlauf, S., Johnson, P. and Temple, J. (2005) Growth
rate) and economic reforms, progress of the financial econometrics, in Handbook of Economic Growth, Vol.
658 B. B. Rao and G. Hassan
1, Chap. 8 (Eds.) P. Aghion, and S. Durlauf, North Senhadji, A. (2000) Sources of economic growth: an exten-
Holland, Amsterdam, pp. 555–677. sive growth accounting exercise, IMF Staff Papers, 47,
Easterly, W. Levine, R. and Roodman, D. (2004) New data, 129–57.
new doubts: a comment on burnside and Dollar’s ‘Aid, Solow, R. (1956) A contribution to the theory of eco-
Policies, and Growth’ (2000), American Economic nomic growth, Quarterly Journal of Economics, 70,
Review, 94, 774–80. 65–94.
Mankiw, N. G., Romer, D. and Weil, D. (1992) A contribu- Solow, R. (1957) Technological change and the aggregate
tion to the empirics of economic growth, Quarterly production function, Review of Economics and
Journal of Economics, 107, 407–37. Statistics, 39, 312–20.
Downloaded by [University of Guelph] at 08:53 30 May 2012

You might also like