You are on page 1of 11

Journal of World Business 39 (2004) 233–243

Strategic factors affecting foreign direct investment decisions


by multi-national enterprises in Latin America
Len J. Treviñoa,*, Franklin G. Mixon Jr.b
a
Department of Management and Decision Sciences, Washington State University, Pullman, WA 99164-4736, USA
b
Department of International Business and Economics, Box 5072, The University of
Southern Mississippi, Hattiesburg, MS 39406-5072, USA

Abstract

Cross-country differences in macroeconomic and institutional environments are used to explain MNE behavior, as proxied by
foreign direct investments (FDIs) inflows to seven Latin American countries, namely Argentina, Brazil, Chile, Columbia,
Mexico, Peru and Venezuela for the period 1988–1999. Results indicate that the institutional approach is dominant, thus
supporting recent FDI research that has included statistical measures of institutional reform in their models. Since MNEs must
conform to the institutional environment prevailing in the host country, managers should undertake FDI where there is minimal
institutional distance between the home and the host country environments. In addition, government officials should place
increased emphasis on institutional reform if their objective is to increase inward FDI in their countries. Finally, any assistance
provided by non-governmental organizations, such as the IMF and the World Bank, should also emphasize institutional reform.
# 2004 Elsevier Inc. All rights reserved.

1. Introduction countries acknowledge that they need outside capital


to achieve their development objectives, partly because
The opening of markets in developing countries in industrial nations have stabilized foreign aid and devel-
recent years has brought with it burgeoning foreign opment loans. Second, export-oriented FDI brings
direct investment (FDI) flows. In the 1990s, FDI relief from rampant foreign exchange shortages. Third,
became the largest single source of external finance recognizing that reversal of portfolio investment is less
for developing countries. By 1997, FDI accounted costly, a fact that exacerbated recent financial crises in
for about half of all private capital and 40% of total a number of developing countries, governments now
capital flows into developing countries. In the past, prefers FDI (UNCTAD, 1999). Fourth, host-country
governments in many developing countries often saw governments recognize that MNEs have access to
multinational enterprises (MNEs) as part of the devel- resources other than capital, that can assist with their
opment problem, due to assertions of exploitation of development (such as technology, management and
the environment and of the labor force. At present, access to foreign markets). Recognizing the long-term
MNEs are seen as part of the development solution for costs of failure to integrate their economies into the
several reasons. First, governments in developing global environment, developing countries have opened
up their markets in order to attract more FDI.
*
Corresponding author. Tel.: þ1-509-335-7850;
There are numerous theories that have been
fax: þ1-509-335-7736. advanced to explain this phenomenon. The macroe-
E-mail address: trevino@wsu.edu (L.J. Treviño). conomic approach (Aliber, 1970; Froot & Stein, 1991;

1090-9516/$ – see front matter # 2004 Elsevier Inc. All rights reserved.
doi:10.1016/j.jwb.2004.04.003
234 L.J. Treviño, F.G. Mixon Jr. / Journal of World Business 39 (2004) 233–243

Grosse & Trevino, 1996) emphasizes why net invest- study were Argentina, Brazil, Chile, Colombia, Mex-
ment among pairs or groups of nations tends to flow in ico, Peru, and Venezuela. Combined, they account for
certain patterns. This theory attempts to explain FDI over 85% of FDI in Latin America.
behavior with macroeconomic variables, such as infla-
tion, national income and exchange rate behavior.
With developing countries undertaking market 2. Foreign direct investment in Latin America:
reforms and becoming more receptive to FDI, a brief history
researchers have begun to apply institutional theory
from the strategic management literature (Kennedy & Foreign direct investment in Latin America has a
Sandler, 1997; Trevino, 1999; Trevino, Daniels, & long history, often dating back to the 19th century.
Arbelaez, 2002) to understand this phenomenon. Insti- Early FDI was primarily export-oriented and/or driven
tutional theory emphasizes the influences of systems by MNEs seeking natural resource supplies. Import
surrounding organizations that shape organizational substitution industrialization in the post-WWII era led
behavior and decision making (Scott, 1995). As such, to a shift in FDI toward manufacturing for domestic
it attempts to explain the organization–environment consumption. Lacking foreign exchange in the 1980s,
interface. According to Hoskisson, Eden, Lau, and many governments in Latin America began to open up
Wright (2000), the role of institutions in an economy is their markets in a return to export-oriented FDI.
to reduce transaction and information costs by redu- Foreign direct investment in Argentina was preva-
cing uncertainty and by establishing a stable structure lent from the late 19th century until the beginning of
that facilitates interactions. Empirical research using WWII. It was initially sought to improve the trans-
an institutional theoretical approach has emphasized portation infrastructure. However, the post-WWII era
the study of political risk, bilateral investment treaties, produced nationalist economies throughout most of
foreign investment and trade regulations, and capital Latin America and, in the case of Argentina, the closed
markets liberalization in an attempt to explain FDI. nationalistic economy continued until the late 1980s,
Although both of these approaches have been culminating in macroeconomic dislocation. This eco-
employed separately (Grosse & Trevino, 1996; Meyer, nomic and institutional landscape led to capital flight
2001) and together (Trevino et al., 2002), no effort has and ultimately to market reform, characterized by
been made to determine the individual importance trade openness, deregulation and privatization. These
relative to each. This paper fills that void by presenting reforms led to increased FDI flows. The foundation of
hypotheses concerning these two approaches. The Argentina’s economic transformation was the Con-
empirical results support the superiority of the institu- vertibility Law, a currency board implemented in
tional construct, thus lending credence to recent stu- 1991. Other important elements included trade liberal-
dies that have employed institutional theory to explain ization, privatization, tax reform, and deregulation
FDI into developing and transitional economies (Tre- (Petrocella & Lousteau, 2001). In the beginning of
vino et al., 2002). the 1990s, the vast majority of FDI flows came in the
Latin America is a useful region for our study form of privatizations. After 1993, FDI flows increas-
because Latin American and Caribbean countries ingly took place in the private sector.
receive a significant portion of FDI inflows going to The role that FDI plays in the modern Brazilian
developing countries (UNCTAD, 1999). In addition, economy is different than that which it played in
debt crises in this region resulted in reduced FDI previous eras. Prior to WWII, FDI was concentrated
inflows during the first half of the 1980s, after which in public utilities, including transportation, in the
they began a steady increase, partially resulting from primary goods export economy, and in banking, with
macroeconomic and institutional liberalization poli- a small percentage in the manufacturing sector. Simi-
cies. Although institutional reform has taken place in lar to Argentina, post-WWII FDI flows shifted to
almost all countries of the region, Latin American manufacturing as part of an import substitution indus-
countries’ liberalization policies, market reforms and trialization strategy. In the 1990s, the role that FDI
inflows of FDI have varied cross-sectionally and over played changed considerably. Brazil adopted institu-
time. The seven countries examined in the current tional and macroeconomic reforms, partially designed
L.J. Treviño, F.G. Mixon Jr. / Journal of World Business 39 (2004) 233–243 235

to stimulate FDI. Elements of these reforms included culminated with the passage of NAFTA. Although
establishment of the real plan, privatization of state- Mexico’s FDI history is similar to that of other Latin
owned enterprises, and implementation of the Merco- American countries, its recent past differs substan-
sur free trade area. It has been estimated that of the tially in that FDI has flowed primarily to newly created
world’s 500 largest corporations, 400 have invest- firms in the maquiladora sector along the U.S. border.
ments in Brazil (Baer & Rangel, 2001), making Brazil In other countries, FDI funds have been primarily
a major source of investment for MNEs and empha- channeled to traditional sectors, such as mining and
sizing the importance of Brazil to the strategy of major energy. The impetus to change Mexico’s FDI policy
MNEs. can be traced to the country’s desperate need for
Chile’s history of FDI is similar to that of other foreign exchange following the 1982 debt crisis. Ele-
Latin American countries, having shifted from invest- ments of market reform included opening of markets
ment in infrastructure development and primary previously closed to foreigners, privatization, dereg-
products to a post-WWII import substitution indus- ulation, national treatment and, of course, NAFTA
trialization policy and, more recently, to manufactur- (Ramirez, 2001).
ing. Although Mexico is known for being one of the Peru began to open its doors to external capital in
earliest countries in Latin America to undertake the early 1990s, somewhat later than other Latin
macroeconomic and institutional reforms, primarily American countries. In an economy fraught with
because of the publicity surrounding NAFTA, Chile populist regimes, foreign debt crises, and political
was the first Latin American country to liberalize its and economic instability, Peru had been effectively
foreign investment regulations. Decree Law 600 was closed to FDI. However, since 1991, macroeconomic
promulgated in 1974 and it liberalized tax codes, and institutional changes included the introduction of
repatriation restrictions, and the foreign exchange a free market policy, the deregulation of prices, the
market. The country’s market reform policies appear adoption of monetary and fiscal control measures
to have been effective because Chile received over $7 (designed to reduce inflation), and privatization
billion in FDI inflows between 1987 and 1994 (Rojas, 2001). All of these elements sent clear signals
(Ramirez, 2001). Continuing with institutional that Peru wanted to become a member of the global
reform, the June 6, 2003 signing of a Chile–U.S. marketplace. Like other countries in the region, pri-
free-trade agreement established clear and transparent vatization has led to increased FDI flows in Peru.
rules for foreign investors, including an open system Oil has defined Venezuela and its FDI regime for
for dispute settlement. over a century. In 1991 and 1992, after a number of
Although Colombia’s history of FDI parallels that technological and financial failures, the state oil com-
of other Latin American countries, liberalization did pany, Petroleos de Venezuela, signed 11 letters of
not take place as a reaction to an economic or foreign intent with transnational oil companies interested in
exchange crisis, or at the beginning of a political pumping crude. Recently, the combination of severe
administration. Nevertheless, radical reforms were economic crisis, coupled with foreign currency
implemented between 1990 and 1994. These included restrictions, has pushed Venezuela farther from
dramatic tariff reductions, liberalization of trade and reforms. The country’s desperate need for foreign
foreign exchange transactions, and financial and capi- capital continues to conflict with its historical desire
tal markets reform. Although Colombia had fewer to exercise sovereignty over its natural resources.
state-owned enterprises than other Latin American
countries, in the early 1990s, some of the banks the
government had absorbed in the financial crisis of the 3. Literature review of macroeconomic
early 1980s were reprivatized, and the government’s variables
stake in the automobile manufacturing sector was sold
(Birch & Halton, 2001). For developing countries to compete for FDI
Mexico, along with Chile, was one of the first inflows, they must implement macroeconomic poli-
countries to abandon import substitution industriali- cies designed to reduce inflation, stabilize the
zation in favor of an open, market-oriented model that exchange rate and increase the GDP of the host
236 L.J. Treviño, F.G. Mixon Jr. / Journal of World Business 39 (2004) 233–243

country. With market-oriented economies in Latin investment historically has been market seeking.
America effectively in operation for little more than Investment in developing countries has been in
a decade, instability of prices, employment and output response to import substitution policies. Although
would be expected. A high rate of inflation is a sign of Tuman and Emmert (1999) used GDP as a surrogate
internal economic instability and of a host govern- for market size and found it to be insignificant in
ment’s inability to maintain expedient monetary pol- explaining FDI among Latin American countries,
icy. From the MNE’s viewpoint, high inflation creates more recently Trevino et al. (2002) found that GDP
uncertainty regarding the net present value of a costly, was a significant and positive indicator of FDI flows in
long-term investment. For these reasons, companies Latin America. Further, UNCTAD (1994) concluded
may avoid making investments in countries with high that market size was the primary determinant of FDI.
inflation. Studies published before Latin American
countries made significant reforms (Schneider & Frey,
1985) as well as those published after reforms were 4. Literature review of institutional variables
enacted (Trevino et al., 2002) confirmed that compa-
nies invested less in developing countries with high Institutional theory in the strategic management
inflation rates. literature suggests that institutions provide the rules
The value of a country’s currency may be under- of the game that structure interactions in societies and
mined by monetary policy or by economic upheaval. posits that organizational action is bound by these
Currency devaluation may result from such policy rules (North, 1990). Within this realm lies political
changes, and foreign investors must incur costs to risk, which may be defined as the risk that a host
prevent transaction and translation losses when host country government will unexpectedly change the
country currencies depreciate. Thus, ceteris paribus, a institutional environment within which businesses
constant real exchange rate is preferred by MNEs in operate (Butler & Joaquin, 1998). From a financial
order to reduce the exchange rate risk inherent with perspective, political risk may alter operating cash
investment in a foreign country. Another perspective flows via discriminatory policies and regulations.
suggests that currency under (over)valuation is an MNEs may deal with political risk by avoiding the
example of market disequilibrium. A currency may risk altogether, by buying insurance, or by negotiating
be defined as undervalued when, at the prevailing rate with the governing body prior to investment. Although
of exchange, production costs for tradable goods are, previous studies reached mixed conclusions about the
on average, lower than in other countries. In this case, effect of political risk on FDI (Grosse & Trevino,
MNEs would be inclined to locate production of 1996; Kobrin, 1979; Tallman, 1988), we expect a
internationally traded goods in countries with under- country with high political risk to be less appealing
valued currencies and to purchase foreign production to foreign investors.
capacity with overvalued foreign exchange (Froot & Capital markets are responsible for mobilizing and
Stein, 1991; Grosse & Trevino, 1996; Klein & allocating capital and for apportioning risk. It is
Rosengren, 1994). From an additional perspective, beneficial when a host country ensures that capital
the apparent under(over) valued exchange rate based flows to its most optimal use and is allocated for
on a firm’s production costs (i.e., wages for a labor- economic, rather than for political reasons. In order
abundant country) denotes that the country has a for developing countries to attract FDI, they must
comparative advantage in producing the product attempt to enforce a capital allocation system with
and MNEs would be inclined to locate a plant within strict and transparent rules and regulations. At the
that host country. same time, they should not exert excessive control
The demand-side of FDI theory argues that invest- over capital account transactions, such as via
ment will go primarily to markets large enough to exchange-rate controls and/or repatriation or foreign
support the scale economies needed for production. ownership restrictions. In an effort to spur internal
This reasoning helps to explain why most FDI goes development, many Latin American countries have
to developed countries rather than to developing enacted capital market reform. If governments main-
countries (Grosse & Trevino, 1996), given that most tain strict control over capital transactions, such as via
L.J. Treviño, F.G. Mixon Jr. / Journal of World Business 39 (2004) 233–243 237

foreign exchange controls and restrictions on FDI, Based on the discussion in the previous two sec-
then MNEs may be reluctant to invest due to fears tions, we expect that:1
about restrictions on new capital formation, divest-
ment and repatriation. b1 ¼ ?
Latin American countries, like their counterparts in b2 < 0
other regions of the world, have been privatizing b3 > 0
government-owned companies. The primary reason b4 > 0
is that many of these companies operated inefficiently b5 > 0
under government ownership. These governments b6 > 0
believe they can reduce their fiscal expenditures
because they will no longer need to subsidize Table 1 presents the findings of an OLS estimation
money-losing operations. In addition to signaling a of Eq. (1).2 The six regressors are jointly significant in
more favorable investment climate, governments can explaining FDI across countries/time. They produce a
receive tax revenue from them if they become profit- sizable R-square for panel data. In four of five cases,
able. From the MNE’s perspective, the potential for our expectations are borne out regarding the signs of
cost savings by transferring technology and manage- the variables. In the case of CPIPC (i.e., the unex-
ment capabilities to the privatized firm is often present pected sign), the parameter estimate is not significant
because most of these companies operated ineffi- at any conventional level. Parameter estimates for
ciently under government ownership. Recent studies RERT, GDPC, and PRSK all are significant at the
of privatization in Latin America (Devlin & Comi- 0.05 level. These results support recent findings by
netti, 1994; Hartenek, 1995; Trevino et al., 2002) Trevino et al. (2002). Lastly, Eq. (1) passes a speci-
concluded that privatization has helped to attract fication error F test (RESET)—failing to reject the
FDI to the region. null hypothesis of ‘‘no specification error’’—at the
0.10 level.3

5. Modeling FDI within the macroeconomic and


institutional frameworks 1
This study uses the political risk measure published by
Institutional Investor (various issues), where a higher number
Eq. (1) presents a test of the macroeconomic indicates more political stability. Although we expect a negative
and institutional theories: relationship between political risk and FDI, this would show up as a
positive coefficient in the equation. Data sources for the other
FDI ¼ b1 RERT þ b2 CPIPC þ b3 GDPC þ b4 CALI variables in Eq. (1) are provided below in a separate section.
2
As Table 1 notes, we used 56 observations in our regressions.
þ b5 PRIV þ b6 PRSK þ e: (1)
For some variables (years), we had missing data. Specifically,
In Eq. (1) FDI represents inward FDI for the seven observations on CALI and PRSK cover the period 1988–1995,
Latin American countries under study for the period those on GDPC and CPIPC cover the periods 1988–1997 and
1988–1998, respectively, while those on RERT and PRIV cover the
1988–1999. RERT is the real exchange rate of Latin period 1988–1999. We selected all the observations at our disposal
American currencies at year-end, per U.S. dollar. where there were no missing data for any of our variable series.
CPIPC represents the annual percentage change in This selection process facilitated the tests of non-nested hypotheses
consumer prices in the host country’s currency. GDPC we detail below.
3
is the host country’s per-capita gross domestic pro- We use the standard RESET procedure from Ramsey (1969).
First, predicted values for FDI are obtained from the OLS model.
duct, in U.S. dollars. CALI is the degree of the host These predicted values are squared and cubed, and enter equation
country’s control over capital account transactions on one as additional regressors (Gujurati, 1988). A RESET F statistic
an annual basis. PRIV is the value of domestic priva- of 1.651 (2, 48 df) is produced regarding the joint significance of
tizations (less FDI) in each country. Lastly, PRSK is these two additional regressors. The insignificance of the F statistic
each host country’s political risk rating. See the ‘‘Data fails to reject the hypothesis of ‘‘no specification error’’ in the base
regression model. Ramsey’s RESET is a useful test for detecting
Sources and Descriptions’’ at the end of this study for many types of specification error, such as omitted variables,
data sources and a more detailed description of the irrelevant variables, nonlinearity, and errors in measurement
variables. (Gujurati, 1988; Kmenta, 1986).
238 L.J. Treviño, F.G. Mixon Jr. / Journal of World Business 39 (2004) 233–243

Table 1 6. Macroeconomic and institutional theories of


Summary of OLS and LSDV regression results dependent variable:
FDI: is either dominant?
FDI

OLS LSDV In order to discern the relative importance of the


Constant 
2.365.02 (1.67) 8.737.99 (1.39) macroeconomic and institutional theories of FDI,
RERT 28.63 (2.01) 5.62 (0.39) additional empirical testing is necessary. Following
CPIPC 0.07 (0.25) 0.15 (0.77) Maddala (1992: 514–518), we re-specify the two
GDPC 0.50 (2.10) 2.32 (1.67) empirical approaches to FDI as Eqs. (2) and (3):
CALI 4.114.34 (2.36) 785.18 (0.40)
PRIV 0.30 (1.78) 0.23 (1.59) H0 : FDI ¼ bXM þ u0 ; (2)
PRSK 83.29 (2.95) 208.80 (3.43)
H1 : FDI ¼ dZIR þ u1 : (3)
Country dummies
Brazil 5.997.70 Again, FDI represents inward FDI for the seven Latin
Chile 10.990 American countries under study for the period 1988–
Columbia 13.723
1999, XM is the vector of the three macroeconomic
Mexico 4.846
Peru 7.669.54 determinants (along with the country dummies) of
Venezuela 9.265.72 FDI, and ZIR is the vector of the three institutional
No. of observations 56 56
variables (along with the country dummies) under
F statistic 5.01 9.53 consideration. The separate hypotheses in Eqs. (2)
Adjusted R2 0.304 0.651 and (3) above are said to be non-nested given that
neither Eq. (2) nor Eq. (3) can be obtained from the
Notes. The numbers in parentheses above are t values. For the
country dummies, t values are not presented to conserve space, other by imposing a restriction (Kennedy, 1998). That
though significance levels are included. is, each equation has variables not included in the

Denotes significance at the 0.10 level. other (Davidson & MacKinnon, 1993; Kmenta, 1986;

Denotes significance at the 0.05 level. Ramanathan, 1998). It is often the case that there are

Denotes significance at the 0.01 level.
competing theories that attempt to explain the same
dependent variable, and the explanatory variables in
the different theories are non-overlapping. Maddala
Because heterogeneity or country effects are very (1992) suggests the use of various joint test (J tests)
common in panel data, we also employ fixed effects, procedures for testing the ‘‘competing’’ theories, but
least squares dummy variable (LSDV) approach to notes that one ‘‘limitation of [these] test[s] is that
modeling Eq. (1). This approach tests for a common [they] sometimes . . . reject both H0 and H1 or accept
constant intercept term by including a dummy variable [both] H0 and H1’’ (Maddala, 1992: 516). For the
series for our seven Latin American countries. In our purposes of this study, Maddala’s concerns are not
specification, Argentina serves as the omitted country. relevant. We follow the novel use of J tests in Mixon
Results from the LSDV model also are presented in and Gibson (2001), where ‘‘complementarity’’ of
Table 1. The LSDV results mirror those of the OLS theories was tested, rather than ‘‘competitiveness,’’
version in terms of the signs for CALI and PRSK. and their J test finding that both H0 and H1 were
CPIPC retains its expected sign in the LSDV model, accepted supported that contention. We also note that
though not in the OLS specification. However, GDPC the models in Eqs. (2) and (3) are not necessarily
and PRIV retain anomalous signs in the LSDV spe- competing theories, however they are non-nested and
cification, though neither is better than marginally the tests suggested by Maddala (1992) may discover
significant in the LSDV column. PRSK is statistically the dominant source of FDI.
different from zero, as are most of the country dummy The procedure for testing H0 (the maintained
coefficients. In fact, a joint F test on the significance of hypothesis) against H1 is as follows: Eq. (3) is esti-
the set of country dummies produces a test statistic of mated by LSDV and the predicted values of FDI are
9.305 ([6, 44] df), suggesting that the LSDV model be obtained (predFDIIR). Eq. (4) below is then estimated:
used instead of the OLS to determine the relative
importance of each FDI theory. FDI ¼ bXM þ aðpredFDIIR Þ þ v: (4)
L.J. Treviño, F.G. Mixon Jr. / Journal of World Business 39 (2004) 233–243 239

The hypothesis that a ¼ 0 is tested. If this hypothesis above, employ the same data panel as the OLS and
is not rejected, then H0 is not rejected by H1. If the LSDV regressions reported in Table 1.
hypothesis is rejected, then H0 is rejected by H1. A test The F statistics in Table 2 support the conclusion of
of H1 (as the maintained hypothesis) against H0 is the J tests. That is, while institutional theory adds to
based on analogous steps, and examines the statistical macroeconomic theory in explaining FDI, macroeco-
significance of l (where l is the counterpart to a). The nomic theory fails to statistically extend institutional
results are presented in Table 1 as the ‘‘Davidson– theory in this regard. This finding lends support to
MacKinnon J tests’’ (Davidson & MacKinnon, 1981; newer studies that have examined the relationship
MacKinnon, 1983). The results indicate that the insti- between institutional reform and FDI (see Hoskisson
tutional model significantly ‘‘adds to’’ the macroeco- et al., 2000; Trevino et al., 2002).
nomic model in explaining inward FDI in Latin
American countries. This result supports the conten-
tion that recent empirical considerations of various 7. FDI decisions by MNEs in Latin America in
measures of institution building have been beneficial response to institutional reform
and that empirical use of these broad concepts has
added to our understanding of the determinants of The relationship between capital markets liberal-
FDI. On the other hand, the J test for H1 vs. H0 fails to ization in Latin America and the expansion strategies
indicate that the macroeconomic model significantly of international banks into the region is one example
‘‘adds to’’ the institutional model. In fact, the coeffi- of FDI decisions made by MNEs in response to
cient for l is negative (i.e., 0.402). institutional reform. Although policies introduced in
Maddala (1992) explains that J tests are, in small Latin America over the last two decades have differed
sample cases, sometimes less rigorous than traditional from country to country, internal reforms can be
F tests. He concludes, what ‘‘. . . all this suggests is segmented into two phases. In the first phase, interest
that in testing non-nested hypotheses, one should use rates were allowed to be determined by market forces,
the J test with higher significance levels and supple- instead of by fiat, and financial resources were allo-
ment it with the F test on the comprehensive model cated on the basis of supply and demand. During the
. . .’’ (Maddala, 1992: 518). first phase of reforms, banks were invited to operate in
F tests are performed by comparing an unrestricted markets in which they did not have prior access. These
model with all six regressors and the country dummies included areas such as leasing and factoring, broker-
to the two models in Eqs. (2) and (3), each of which is age underwriting and pension fund management. With
restricted to three regressors and the country dummies. economies of scale and scope becoming an increas-
Unlike the one-degree-of-freedom J tests, the F tests ingly important factor to foreign banks, the ability to
reported in Table 2 are based on the error sum of operate in these areas was seen as increasingly impor-
squares (ESS) from LSDVestimation and represent [3, tant to their plans to globalize operations. In the
44] degrees of freedom. Our F tests, as did the J tests second phase, banks were required to maintain more
conservative capital to asset ratios, to impose more
stringent requirements on loans, and to provide more
Table 2
Tests of non-nested hypotheses (H0 ¼ macroeconomic model;
uniform and transparent information to governing
H1 ¼ institutional model) bodies. The financial reforms enacted during the
1990s openly encouraged the entry of foreign banks
Davidson–MacKinnon
into Latin America. The second phase of reforms
J tests F tests created a regulatory environment similar to that of
Test of H0 over H1 
1.249 (4.50) 7.222 international banks’ home country environments, in
Test of H1 over H0 0.402 (0.89) 1.098 the process creating a more certain investment climate
and opening the door for foreign banks to operate in
Notes. The numbers in parentheses above are t values for the J tests
regression parameters. The F statistics above reflect tests with [3,
the local market. Capital markets liberalization, thus,
44] df. helped to create an environment with appropriate

Denotes significance at the 0.01 level. institutions and removed the entry barriers for foreign
240 L.J. Treviño, F.G. Mixon Jr. / Journal of World Business 39 (2004) 233–243

banks, enabling them to expand into Latin America operations resulting from liberalization policies within
and to gain an increasingly large market share in the the European Union with institutional reform in Latin
region (ECLAC, 2003). America, SCH’s and BBVA’s international expansion
One example of a multinational bank that has made in Latin America was a natural outcome.
significant inroads into Latin America in the post- Institutional reform was initiated in the early 1990s
reform era is Citigroup, one of the world’s largest in much of Latin America in response to shortcomings
financial institutions. In fact, it is the largest bank in in many sectors, including a lack of public funds for
Latin America, based on share of regional lending investment and gaps in technology. During this time-
(ECLAC, 2003). Although Citigroup has had a pre- frame, governments introduced reforms designed to
sence in Latin American for well over a century, its attract foreign private capital. Although reforms took
presence was largely limited to corporate and private place in many sectors, nowhere is this policy more
banking services. This strategy was due in large part to evident than in the telecommunications sector. In the
its awareness of institutional weaknesses in Latin early years of reform, many Latin American countries
America that led to the debt crises of the 1980s and privatized their public telecommunications companies
1990s, and ultimately to institutional reform. The and allowed unprecedented foreign participation,
bank’s strategy shifted abruptly in 2001, when it moved attracting large investments and substantial improve-
full force into consumer banking with the well-pub- ments in the telecommunications infrastructure.
licized $12.5 billion acquisition of Mexico’s Banamex- It was not long before the impact of privatization
Accival financial group. This was the single largest FDI programs in Latin America was realized, with Tele-
transaction in Latin America to date. Citibank’s bold fonica of Spain making its presence felt in the region
shift in strategy allowed it to gain control of over 25% early on. In 1991, it became part of a consortium led
of consumer and corporate banking in Mexico. Citi- by GTE Corporation (now Verizon Communications)
bank’s FDI decision making in Latin America is that became majority owner of Telefonos de Vene-
directly related to the liberalization and deregulation zuela, with a nearly $2 billion investment. Shortly
of international financial markets in the region. thereafter, Telefonica of Spain expanded its Latin
Although Citigroup has made significant inroads American operations, investing another $2 billion to
into Latin America, two Spanish banks’, Banco San- acquire a 40% stake in two Peruvian companies,
tender Central Hispano (SCH) and Banco Bilbao Empresa Nacional de telecommunicaciones, a domes-
Vizcaya Argentaria (BBVA), expansion strategies in tic and international long distance monopoly, and
the region have been even more aggressive. Their Compania Peruana de Telefonos, the local telephone
initial strategy was to become a force in consumer company of Lima, the country’s capital. The two
banking, which had shed itself of most institutional companies subsequently merged to form Telefonica
controls and that was seen as having the greatest de Peru, and in 2000 Telefonica of Spain gained
growth potential. Both of these Spanish banks went complete control of this company with an investment
on a buying spree in Latin America during the time of over $3 billion. Telefonica of Spain is a prime
when first and second generation reforms were imple- example of a MNE that has responded to privatization
mented. Between 1997 and 2002, SCH made 26 reform and it has consolidated its position as a leading
acquisitions valued at over $13 billion in all of the provider of fixed and mobile telephony in both Vene-
countries that we studied, in addition to Bolivia and zuela and Peru. In Peru, it has retained its dominant
Paraguay. During the same timeframe, BBVA made 12 position, but in the larger market of Venezuela, it has
acquisitions valued at over $6 billion in six of the faced considerable competition due to liberalization of
seven countries that were the focus of this study in the mobile market combined with the expansionist
addition to an investment in Uruguay. Spanish banks’ strategy of Bell South.
acquisition strategies in Latin America can be traced Institutional reform and privatization in the region
to liberalization policies within the European Union has attracted other international investors into Peru
because these internal liberalization policies pushed and Venezuela, such as Bell South of the United
European banks into expansionist modes to gain States. Bell South responded to Latin America’s desire
economies of scale. Coupling the need to globalize for increased FDI in telecommunications and, as such,
L.J. Treviño, F.G. Mixon Jr. / Journal of World Business 39 (2004) 233–243 241

it has become the leading provider of mobile tele- and normative institutions of two countries) provide
phone services in Venezuela and Colombia and num- alternate and complementary explanations for MNE
ber two in Peru. In fact, Bell South’s Venezuelan behavior (see Kostova & Zaheer, 1999; Trevino et al.,
subsidiary has captured nearly 60% of the market 2002; Xu & Shenkar, 2002). In this paper, we use
and plans to invest an additional $1.5 billion by cross-country differences in macroeconomic and insti-
2005 (ECLAC, 2003). More recent acquisitions made tutional environments to explain MNE behavior, prox-
by Bell South in response to concessions made by the ied by FDI inflows to seven Latin American countries.
Colombian government include a $300 million stake Because it is well established that in order to survive,
in Celumovil, a mobile telecommunications company MNEs must conform to the institutional environment
operating in 6 of Colombia’s 10 largest cities. This prevailing in the host country (DiMaggio & Powell,
investment, coupled with the acquisition of Compania 1991), firms should understand the level of macro-
Celular de Colombia, for which it paid over $400 economic and institutional reform that has taken place
million, gave Bell South the largest share of the in proposed host countries, such as those in Latin
Colombian mobile telecommunications market America. To assist in this understanding, managers of
(ECLAC, 2003). In Peru, where privatization of the MNEs could develop and/or apply separate statistical
telecommunications sector has been more liberal than indices comprising macroeconomic and institutional
in Colombia, Bell South bought Tele 2000, a multi- information for proposed host countries. Empirical
service telecommunications company, initiated its results presented here suggest that managers should
own fiber optics network in the country and introduced take particular care to examine host country institu-
the Bell South brand. The Bell South example high- tional environments (reforms), and a longitudinal data
lights MNEs’ FDI strategic decision making in Latin base (of indices for individual countries) could be
America in response to host governments’ privatiza- useful to managers in formulating FDI strategies.
tion strategies designed to attract FDI. These indices could go well beyond those institutional
Institutional reforms introduced in Latin American factors examined here. For instance, aspects of labor
countries in the early 1990s were swift and decisive market law—an important consideration in Brazil—
and the MNE strategic response was predictable. As a could be indexed to supplement information on poli-
result of institutional reform in the region, the Per- tical risk and other institutional factors.
uvian government estimates that it has received over Our results may also prove useful to public admin-
$4 billion in private investment in the telecommunica- istrators in proposed host countries, as well as to
tions industry between 1997 and 2001 and that addi- administrators and decision-making boards of interna-
tional agreements have been signed with Telefonica of tional development agencies around the world. Given
Spain and with AT&T of the United States worth the statistical dominance of institutional theory in our
another $5 billion. Similarly, over $5 billion in private model, government officials and politicians should
capital flowed into the telecommunications industry in place greater (lesser) emphasis on institutional reform
Venezuela between 1997 and 2001. (macroeconomic conditions) in order to attract greater
levels of inward FDI. This refocusing of effort would
likely exhibit a higher marginal productivity given the
8. Managerial implications greater scope for political/public influence on a coun-
try’s institutional framework rather than its macroeco-
Most agree that the economies of developing coun- nomic environment (Barro, 1997, 1999). Additionally,
tries are inextricably tied to MNEs and private invest- our results also indicate that administrators and advi-
ment. In addition, it has been shown that MNEs can sory boards of public agencies that are involved with
enhance their own bottom line by investing even in the international development efforts, such as UNCTAD,
poorest economies of the world (Prahalad & Ham- the International Monetary Fund and The World Bank,
mond, 2002). While earlier explanations of FDI were should also consider a similar refocusing of effort.
dominated by economic theories, more recently insti- Many of these agencies often are preoccupied with
tutional theory and institutional distance (i.e., the assisting LDCs in producing macroeconomic policies
extent of similarity between the regulatory, cognitive that are helpful with economic development. Our
242 L.J. Treviño, F.G. Mixon Jr. / Journal of World Business 39 (2004) 233–243

results suggest that any assistance provided by either Gujurati, D. N. (1988). Basic econometrics. New York: McGraw-
Hill.
the IMF or the WB should, perhaps, be geared toward
Hartenek, G. (1995). Privatization as a catalyst for FDI: The case of
institutional reform. Not only does institutional theory Argentina. In Foreign direct investment: OECD countries and
appear to dominate macroeconomic theories concern- dynamic economies of Asia and Latin America. Washington,
ing MNE’s decision to locate outward FDI, these public DC: OECD Publications and Information Center.
lending enterprises have a vested interest in assuring Hoskisson, R., Eden, L., Lau, C. M., & Wright, M. (2000). Strategy
that the marginal productivity of their own assistance in emerging economies. Academy of Management Journal,
43(3): 249–267.
efforts is increased. Kennedy, P. (1998). A guide to econometrics. Cambridge, MA: The
MIT Press.
Kennedy, R. E., & Sandler, A. (1997). Transition to a market
Acknowledgments economy: The components of reform [Case No. 9-797-080,
Mimeo]. Harvard Business School.
Klein, M., & Rosengren, E. (1994). The real exchange rate and
The authors thank two anonymous referees of this foreign direct investment in the United States: Relative wealth
journal, Frank Hoy, and Kamal Upadhyaya for helpful versus relative wage effects. Journal of International
comments. Economics, 36(3/4): 373–389.
Kmenta, J. (1986). Elements of econometrics. New York:
Macmillan Publishing Company.
Kobrin, S. J. (1979). Political risk: A review and reconsideration.
References Journal of International Business Studies, 10(1): 67–80.
Kostova, T., & Zaheer, S. (1999). Organizational legitimacy
Aliber, R. Z. (1970). A theory of foreign direct investment. In C. P. under conditions of complexity: The case of the multi-
Kindleberger (Ed.), The international corporation. Cambridge, national enterprise. Academy of Management Review, 24(1):
MA: The MIT Press. 64–81.
Baer, W., & Rangel, G. B. (2001). Foreign investment in the age of MacKinnon, J. G. (1983). Model specification tests against non-
globalization: The case of Brazil. Latin American Business nested alternatives. Econometric Reviews, 2(1): 85–158.
Review, 2(1/2): 83–99. Maddala, G. S. (1992). Introduction to econometrics. New York,
Barro, R. J. (1997). Getting it right: Markets and choices in a free NY: Macmillan Publishing Company.
society. Cambridge, MA: The MIT Press. Meyer, K. (2001). Institutions, transaction costs and entry mode
Barro, R. J. (1999). Determinants of economic growth: A cross- choice in Eastern Europe. Journal of International Business
country empirical study. Cambridge, MA: The MIT Press. Studies, 32(2): 357–367.
Birch, M. H., & Halton, G. (2001). Foreign direct investment in Latin Mixon, F.G., Jr., & Gibson, M. T. (2001). The retention of
America in the 1990s: Old patterns, new trends, and emerging state level concealed handgun laws: Empirical evidence from
issues. Latin American Business Review, 2(1/2): 13–31. interest group and legislative models. Public Choice, 107(1/2):
Butler, K. C., & Joaquin, D. C. (1998). A note on political risk and 1–20.
the required return on foreign direct investment. Journal of North, D. (1990). Institutions, institutional change and economic
International Business Studies, 29(3): 599–608. performance. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.
Davidson, R., & MacKinnon, J. G. (1981). Several tests for model Petrocella, D., & Lousteau, M. (2001). FDI in Argentina during the
specification in the presence of alternative hypotheses. 1990s. Latin American Business Review, 2(1/2): 33–54.
Econometrica, 49(5): 781–793. Prahalad, C. K., & Hammond, A. (2002). Serving the world’s poor,
Davidson, R., & MacKinnon, J. G. (1993). Estimation and profitably. Harvard Business Review, 80(9): 48–57.
inference in econometrics. Oxford: Oxford University Press. Ramanathan, R. (1998). Introductory econometrics with applica-
Devlin, R., & Cominetti, R. (1994). La Crisis de la Empresa Publica, tions. New York: Harcourt Brace & Company.
Las Privatizaciones y la Equidad Social. In Reformas de politica Ramirez, M. D. (2001). Foreign direct investment in Mexico and
publica: 1–35 (Vol. 26) (LC/L 832). Santiago, Chile: CEPAL. Chile: A critical appraisal. Latin American Business Review,
DiMaggio, P. J., & Powell, W. W. (1991). Introduction. In W. W. 2(1/2): 55–82.
Powell & P. J. DiMaggio (Eds.), The new institutionalism in Ramsey, J. B. (1969). Tests for specification error in classical linear
organizational analysis: 1–38. Chicago: University of Chicago least squares regression analysis. Journal of the Royal
Press. Statistical Society, 31(Series B): 250–271.
Froot, K. A., & Stein, J. C. (1991). Exchange rates and foreign Rojas, (2001). The increased role of capital in the Peruvian
direct investment: An imperfect capital markets approach. financial system: 1990–1998. Latin American Business Review,
Quarterly Journal of Economics, 106(November): 1191–1217. 2(1/2): 101–118.
Grosse, R., & Trevino, L. J. (1996). Foreign direct investment in Schneider, F., & Frey, B. S. (1985). Economic and political
the United States: An analysis by country of origin. Journal of determinants of foreign direct investment. World Development,
International Business Studies, 27(1): 139–155. 13(2): 161–175.
L.J. Treviño, F.G. Mixon Jr. / Journal of World Business 39 (2004) 233–243 243

Scott, W. R. (1995). Institutions and organizations. Thousand Tuman, J. P., & Emmert, C. F. (1999). Explaining Japanese foreign
Oaks, CA: Sage. direct investment in Latin America, 1979–1992. Social Science
Tallman, S. B. (1988). Home country political risk and foreign Quarterly, 80(3): 539–541.
direct investment in the United States. Journal of International United Nations Conference on Trade and Development. (1994).
Business Studies, 19(2): 219–234. World Investment Report 1994: Transnational corporations,
Trevino, L. J. (1999). Market reform and foreign direct investment employment and the workplace. New York and Geneva:
in Central and Eastern Europe: A comparative assessment. In UNCTAD.
D. K. Despotis & C. Zopounidis (Eds.), Proceedings of United Nations Conference on Trade and Development. (1999).
Decision Sciences Institute. Athens: New Technologies Pub- World Investment Report 1999: Foreign direct investment and
lications. the challenge of development. New York, NY: UNCTAD.
Trevino, L. J., Daniels, J. D., & Arbelaez, H. (2002). Market reform Xu, D., & Shenkar, O. (2002). Institutional distance and the
and FDI in Latin America: An empirical investigation. multinational enterprise. Academy of Management Review,
Transnational Corporations, 11(1): 29–48. 27(4): 608–618.

You might also like