You are on page 1of 11

Journal of Applied Economic Sciences

PUBLIC DEBT AND ECONOMIC GROWTH IN THE EUROPEAN UNION


Piotr MISZTAL Technical University in Radom, Poland Economics Department misztal@tkdami.net
Abstract The main aim of the article is to present the relationships between public debt and economic growth in the European Union in the period 20002010. The article consists of two parts. The first part deals with theoretical analysis of the relationships between public debt and economic growth, including reasons and factors determining these relationships. In the next part of article, there are examined the relationships between public debt and gross domestic product in the EU by using the Vector Autoregression Model (VAR). There are estimated elasticity coefficients of public debt to GDP and elasticity coefficients of GDP to public debt on the base of impulse response function. Then, there is made variance decomposition of the public debt and GDP in order to assess the impact of these factors on the variability of GDP and public debt respectively. Keywords: public debt, budget deficit, economic growth, crowdin effect JEL Classification: H6

1. Introduction The issue concerning the impact of public debt on the economic growth was and still is one of the subjects of the debate among theorists and practitioners of economics. Basically, in the economics literature on this subject, theoretical and empirical considerations can be divided into three main groups. The first group of analyses constitutes works of Keynesians, the second, research of the Neo classical School representatives and the third, studies of proponents of the Ricardian Equivalence hypothesis. These three contrasting approaches to budget deficit and public debt contribute to many discussions in the country and abroad on the role of budget deficit and public debt in the process of economic growth. 2. Model of budget deficit, public debt and economic growth Budget deficit is typically defined as the difference between government expenditure (including interest on debt) and government income. However, in accordance with the more complex definition, budget deficit is the difference between the size of public debt at the end of the year and the size of public debt at the end of the previous year. These two definitions are equivalent if the public debt is defined as the value of issued bonds. Budget deficit in country implies that public debt increases. But because GDP also increases, the ratio of government debt to GDP may change or remain stable. Therefore, whether the ratio of government debt to GDP varies or remains unchanged that depends on the growth rate of the national debt is greater or less than the GDP growth rate. Systematically increasing the ratio of domestic debt to GDP is a threat for the country, the public debt will enter the unsustainable growth path, leading to the insolvency of the country. Even if the ratio of public debt to GDP does not increase rapidly, high debttoGDP ratio is serious and unfavorable consequences for the country associated the growing cost of public debt service. Therefore it is important to understand the causes of the increase the ratio of public debt to GDP and to find the optimal size of this ratio in the country. For this purpose it is necessary to distinguish the standard budget deficit from the primary budget deficit. Basic (primary) budget deficit is equal to the standard budget deficit corrected by the cost of public debt service (Feldstein 2004). Therefore, standard budget deficit and the primary budget deficit can be presented in the form of the following expressions, as:

SB = G + (i PD ) T

(1) (2)

PB = G T

292

Volume V/ Issue 3(13)/ Fall 2010

where: SB standard budget deficit; PB basic budget deficit; PD public debt; G government expenditure; i interest of public debt; T government incomes (tax and nontax). Hence, on the basis of the above mentioned expressions we can present the ratio of public debt to GDP in the following form:

PD G T GDP PD = + i GDP GDP GDP GDP

(3)

where: GDP gross domestic product. In accordance with Equation 3, the ratio of public debt to GDP is the sum of the ratio of primary budget deficit to GDP and the difference between the interest rate and the growth rate of GDP multiplied by the ratio of government debt to GDP. Therefore, in accordance with the above mentioned equation the ratio of government debt to GDP rises when in the situation of the primary budget deficit, interest of public debt is greater than the growth rate of GDP. In order to reduce the ratio of public debt to GDP it must be the surplus in the primary government balance (greater government income than public expenditure) or GDP must grow faster than the cost of public debt service. 3. Literature review on the public debt and economic growth According to Keynesian opinions, budget deficit and the public debt have a positive impact on economic activity in the country, in particular through the mechanism of public expenditure multiplayer. Moreover, they provide arguments indicating the prevalence of crowdin effect in public expenditure as a result of deficits and debt induced by expansionary fiscal policy. They also argue that budget deficit and government debt increase national production, what makes that private investors perceive the future economic situation more optimistic and increase their investments. On the other hand, representatives of the Neoclassical School state that the budget deficit and public debt can make harmful effects for economic growth. They analyze consumption expenditure of households during their entire life cycle and consider that the government with budget deficit moves the tax burden on future generations, what leads to increase of current consumption. On the assumption of full employment, representatives of the Neoclassical School argue that increasing consumption means decreasing savings. Therefore interest rates must increase in order to restore equilibrium on the capital market what leads to decrease the size of private investment (Keho 2010). However, advocates of the Ricardian Equivalence conception argue that government deficit and public debt are neutral for economic growth. According to this hypothesis the current budget deficit, resulting for example from tax decreasing must be repaid in the future, for example by tax increasing, thus leaving private investments and interest rates unchanged (Saleh 2003). Some economists, such as Modigliani (1961), Diamond (1965), and SaintPaul (1992) indicate that increasing public debt always contributes to economic growth. In turn, Patillo, Poirson, and Ricci (2004) concluded that the low level of public debt affects positively economic growth but high public debt affects negatively the growth rate of GDP. Furthermore, the results of empirical studies carried out by Kumar, and Woo (2010) on a group of countries including both developed economies, as well as developing countries indicate the presence of negative relationship between initial public debt and economic growth in the period 19702007. The results of their analyses confirmed that the increase in the ratio of public debt to GDP by 10 p.p. accompanied the decline in real GDP per capita by 0.2 p.p. within one year. Schclarek (2005) analyzing 59 developing countries and 24 developed economies stated that in the case of developing countries it is always negative and substantial relationship between the total indebtedness of the country and economic growth. On the other hand, in relation to high developed

293

Journal of Applied Economic Sciences

countries Schclarek (2004) did not find a significant relationship between the public debt and economic growth. Ferreira (2009) analyzed the relationship between economic growth and public debt using vector autoregression model and Granger causality test confirmed the existence of the relationship between economic growth per capita and the ratio of public debt to GDP in OECD member countries over the period 19882001. Furthermore, he confirmed that this relationship is always bidirectional. Keho (2010) examined the relation between budget deficit and economic growth in seven West African countries in the period 19802005 using VAR model and Granger causality test. He obtained inconclusive results. In the case of the three countries he did not find a causal relationship between budget deficit and economic growth. But in the case of three other countries he found twoway, negative relationship between fiscal balance and economic growth. Simultaneously, it should be emphasized that many empirical studies conducted over the past several years suggests a nonlinear relationship between the public debt and economic growth (Moore, Chrystol 2008). Namely, the results of these studies indicate that public debt positively affect economic growth, but only to a certain level of the debt in relation to GDP. To similar conclusions came Elbadawi, Ndulu, and Ndungu (1997) analyzing the relationship between public debt and GDP in 26 subSaharan African countries in the period 19801994. They have demonstrated that public debt positively affected economic growth in these countries, but only up to 97% of GDP. Similarly, Pattillo, Poirson, Ricci (2002) examined 93 developing countries in the period 19721998 and they found positive impact of public debt on GDP growth rate, but only up to 3540% of GDP. Similar studies conducted Smyth, and Hsing (1995), who analyzed the impact of public debt on economic growth in the USA in the 80s and 90s of the 20th century. However, these authors assessed an optimal level of public debt (the level of public debt, which maximizes economic growth) for the U.S. economy. Their results indicated that an optimal level of public debt to GDP for American economy amounted to 38.4% in the analyzed period. Reinhart, and Rogoff (2010) examining 44 developed and developing countries over the last hundred years concluded that the high level of public debt in relation to GDP (over 90%) is accompanied by a lower level of economic growth in developed countries as well as in developing countries. Furthermore, in the case of developing countries, the relatively high level of external debt in relation to GDP (over 60%) negatively affected economic growth. 4. Public debt and economic growth in the EU in the period 20002010 Relatively high size of public debt in many EU member countries contributed to numerous discussions on the impact of public debt on economic growth (Biondo 2010). In order to analyze the causal relationship between changes of public debt and GDP in the EU member countries in the period 20002010 there was used vector autoregression model (VAR) proposed by Ferreira (2009) and presented by the following expressions:

GDPi ,t = k GDPi ,t k + k PDi ,t k + i ,t


k =1 k =1

(4) (5)

PDi, t = k PDi ,t k + k GDPi ,t k + i ,t


k =1 k =1

where: PD public debt expressed in national currency; GDP gross domestic product expressed in national currency; , residuals; tgiven period; klag length. All the above mentioned time series had quarterly frequency and cover the period from the first quarter of 2000 to the first quarter of 2010. These data came from the base of the European Union Statistical Office (Eurostat). Before the model structural parameters were estimated, it was necessary to isolate a seasonal factor from the time series. The existence of a seasonal factor in the time series

294

Volume V/ Issue 3(13)/ Fall 2010

could lead to difficulties in interpreting changes in a given phenomenon in the analyzed period. To eliminate the time series from seasonal fluctuations, the X12ARIMA method was applied. Moreover, it was necessary to specify the stationarity of the analyzed time series. For this purpose the Augmented DickeyFuller Test (ADF) was used. Among analyzed variables there were time series of the integration degree 0 and 1. The lack of stationarity of time series forced the modification of function model, in order to bring the variables to stationarity. This modification was to replace the size of variables by their first differences. It should be also pointed out that in the absence of cointegration between variables there was no possible to expand and transform structural VAR model into the Error Correction Model (ECM). In the analysis one lag period (one quarter) between explanatory variables was adopted. The choice of lag lengths was in line with the results of the information criteria of the Akaike, Schwartz Bayesian and the HannanQuinn models. According to these criteria, a model with one lag length was characterized by the biggest information capacity. Analyzing ratios of public debt to GDP in the EU it can be noted that these indicators increased significantly over the past ten years. The average share of public debt in GDP in the 27 EU member states was 65% at the beginning of 2000 and at the beginning of 2010 this ratio was about 75%. The highest ratios of public debt to GDP were found in Greece, Italy and Belgium but the lowest in Estonia, Luxembourg and Bulgaria.
120.0 100.0 80.0 60.0 40.0 20.0 0.0

Figure 1. The ratios of public debt to GDP in the EU member countries in years 2000 and 2010 [in %] Source: Own calculations on the basis of Eurostat (2010).

Moreover, the size of GDP per capita in the EU increased substantially over the past few years. The average level of GDP per capita in the 27 EU member countries was 19 thousand euro at the beginning of 2000 and 24 thousand euro at the beginning of 2010. The highest sizes of GDP per capita in 2010 were in Luxembourg, Denmark and Ireland, but the lowest in Romania, Bulgaria, Lithuania and Latvia.

EU Belgium Bulgaria Czech Rep. Denmark Germany Estonia Ireland Greece S pain France It aly Cyprus Latvia Lithuania Luxembourg Hungary Malta Net herlands Austria Poland Portugal Romania S lovenia S lovakia Finland S weden UK

2010

2000

295

Journal of Applied Economic Sciences

80000 70000 60000 50000 40000 30000 20000 10000


EU Belgium Bulgaria Czech Rep. Denmark Germany Estonia Ireland Greece S pain France It aly Cyprus Latvia Lithuania Luxembourg Hungary Malta Net herlands Austria Poland Portugal Romania S lovenia S lovakia Finland S weden UK

2010

2000

Figure 2. Size of GDP per capita in the EU member countries in years 2000 and 2010 [in euro] Source: Own calculations on the basis of Eurostat (2010).

From a theoretical point of view, less economically developed countries should have generally higher level of public debt in relation to GDP than highly developed countries due to financial constraints and economic needs in poorer countries. However, analyzing data concerning the share of public debt in GDP in the EU member countries we may notice higher ratios of public debt to GDP in relatively high developed EU member countries. This may indicate a positive impact of public debt on the level of economic development of these countries or the positive impact of the economic growth on the size of public debt. However, the experience of many countries, both developed, as well as developing shows that too high share of public debt in GDP may increase the risk of investment in the country, the outflow of foreign capital and consequently the depreciation of the national currency. Of course, this situation negatively affects the rate growth of GDP in the country. In order to find a causal relationship between the average level of public debt and GDP in the EU in the period 20002010 it was necessary to estimate structural parameters of VAR model. Results of parameters estimation of the model were shown in the following table.
Table 1. The results of structural parameters estimation of VAR model VAR system, lag order 1 OLS estimates, observations 2000:22010:1 (T = 40) Loglikelihood = 258,18577 Determinant of covariance matrix = 8,4843479e009 AIC = 12,7093 BIC = 12,5404 HQC = 12,6482 Portmanteau test: LB(10) = 67,6214, df = 36 [0,0011] Equation 1: GDP Coefficient Std. Error 1,32922 0,167257 0,334161 0,169398 0.861849 0.0250165 0.145892 0.0265551 tratio 7,9472 1,9726 34.4513 5.4939 pvalue <0,00001 *** 0,05585 * <0.00001 *** <0.00001 ***

GDP_1 PD_1 GDP_1 PD_1

296

Volume V/ Issue 3(13)/ Fall 2010

Mean dependent var Sum squared resid Rsquared F(2, 38) rho

15,71887 0,006189 0,999999 30343398 0,199296

S.D. dependent var S.E. of regression Adjusted Rsquared Pvalue(F) DurbinWatson

0,121356 0,012762 0,999999 1,4e118 1,504455

Ftests of zero restrictions: All lags of GDP F(1, 38) = 63,158 [0,0000] All lags of PD F(1, 38) = 3,8913 [0,0558] Equation 2: PD Coefficient Std. Error 0,430476 0,168944 0,563264 0,171107 15,51963 0,006314 0,999999 28991312 0,049724

GDP_1 PD_1 Mean dependent var Sum squared resid Rsquared F(2, 38) rho

tratio 2,5480 3,2919

pvalue 0,01500 ** 0,00216 *** 0,123634 0,012891 0,999999 3,3e118 1,828029

S.D. dependent var S.E. of regression Adjusted Rsquared Pvalue(F) DurbinWatson

Ftests of zero restrictions: All lags of GDP F(1, 38) = 6,4925 [0,0150] All lags of PD F(1, 38) = 10,837 [0,0022] Source: Own calculations.

On the basis of the estimation results of the Equation 4 (GDP), we can see that one of the factors that determined GDP growth in the EU in the period 20002010 was public debt. Namely, the increase in public debt by 1% led to decline the value of GDP on average by 0.3%. On the other hand, on the basis of the estimation results of the Equation 5 (PD) it was affirmed that one of the most important factors which determined the size of public debt in the EU in the period 20002010 were just GDP changes. In this case, GDP growth by 1% led to increase public debt on average by about 0.4%. However, comparing the elasticity coefficients in these two equations it was proved that GDP changes affected the size of public debt in much more degree, than public debt influenced on GDP growth in the EU in the examined period. The next step of analysis was the measurement of the impact strength of public debt changes on GDP and GDP changes on the size of public debt in the EU. It was made using the socalled impulse response function, i.e., function of a GDP and public debt response to an impulse resulting from one unit changes of public debt and GDP respectively.

297

Journal of Applied Economic Sciences

GDP -> GDP 0.019 0.018 0.017 0.016 0.015 0.014 0.013 0.012 0 2 4 6 8 10 12 14 16 18 20 quarters PD -> GDP 0 -0.005 -0.01 -0.005 -0.015 -0.01 -0.02 -0.025 0 2 4 6 8 10 12 14 16 18 20 quarters -0.015 -0.02 0 2 4 6 0.01 0.005 0 0.018 0.017 0.016 0.015 0.014 0.013 0.012 0.011 0.01 0 2 4 6

GDP -> PD

10

12

14

16

18

20

quarters PD -> PD

10

12

14

16

18

20

quarters

Figure 3. Impulse response function of gross domestic product (GDP) and public debt (PD) to a one shock in public debt and gross domestic product Source: Own calculations.

On the basis of above figure, it was noted one shock change in GDP led to the gradual growth of GDP over the next twenty quarters from the time of shock, and subsequently to stabilization. What is more, the increase of GDP led to increase in the size of public debt over next 20 quarters, and then to gradual stabilization. The situation seemed differently in the case of GDP reaction to changes in the size of public debt. The increase of public debt led to the gradual decrease of GDP over the next twenty quarters, and subsequently to gradual stabilization. However, one shock change in size of public debt led to an immediate increase in public debt and then to gradual decline during the next twenty quarters. The last step of the analysis was the residual component variance decomposition of public debt and GDP, in order to estimate the impact of these factors on the variability of GDP and public debt respectively in the EU.
Table 2. The error variance decomposition for public debt and gross domestic product in the EU in the period 20002010 The number of quarter after shock 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 10 11 12 13 The error variance decomposition for variable PD PD GDP 34,7 24,3 16,8 12,5 11,2 11,9 13,8 16,4 19,3 22,1 24,9 27,5 29,9 The error variance decomposition for variable GDP PD GDP 0,0 100,0 1,8 98,2 5,1 94,9 9,1 90,9 13,2 86,8 17,1 82,9 20,8 79,2 24,1 75,9 27,0 73,0 29,7 70,3 32,1 67,9 34,2 65,8 36,1 63,9

65,3 75,7 83,2 87,5 88,8 88,1 86,2 83,6 80,7 77,9 75,1 72,5 70,1

298

Volume V/ Issue 3(13)/ Fall 2010

The number of quarter after shock 14 15 16 17 18 19 20

The error variance decomposition for variable PD PD GDP 32,1 34,0 35,8 37,4 38,9 40,2 41,4

67,9 66,0 64,2 62,6 61,1 59,8 58,6

The error variance decomposition for variable GDP PD GDP 37,7 62,3 39,2 60,8 40,6 59,4 41,8 58,2 42,9 57,1 43,9 56,1 44,8 55,2

Source: Own calculations.

In accordance with data in above table it can be noted that GDP changes accounted for 87% of the public debt variance in the EU after fourth quarter and nearly 59% after twentieth quarter. For comparison, changes in the size of the public debt in the EU explained about 9% changes of GDP at the end of the fourth quarter and close to 45% after twentieth quarter. The impact of public debt on economic growth and the impact of economic growth on public debt significantly varied in size among the individual EU member countries. Namely, the highest absolute values of impact coefficients of public debt to GDP were affirmed in Spain and Ireland, and the lowest value in Latvia. On the other hand, the highest absolute values of impact coefficients of GDP to public debt were found in Finland and the smallest in Spain, Ireland, Slovenia, Sweden, Denmark, Netherlands and Cyprus.
Table 3. Elasticity coefficients of public debt to GDP and elasticity coefficients of GDP to public debt in the EU member countries in the period 20002010 Country Belgium Bulgaria Czech Rep. Denmark Germany Estonia Ireland Greece Spain France Italy Cyprus Latvia Lithuania Luxembourg Hungary Malta Netherlands Austria Poland Portugal Romania Slovenia Slovakia Finland Sweden UK Source: Own calculations. GDP PD 0,01 0,04 0,02 0,06 0,02 0,08 0,29 0,07 0,32 0,03 0,05 0,04 0,00 0,05 0,02 0,09 0,01 0,01 0,01 0,01 0,03 0,02 0,24 0,03 0,03 0,12 0,02 PD GDP 0,02 0,01 0,07 0,00 0,05 0,05 0,00 0,06 0,00 0,06 0,06 0,00 0,11 0,09 0,07 0,01 0,32 0,00 0,15 0,06 0,03 0,09 0,00 0,17 0,49 0,00 0,10

299

Journal of Applied Economic Sciences

Analyzing values of elasticity coefficients of GDP to public debt and public debt to GDP in each of the EU member countries it was identified certain regularities. Generally speaking, it was found the highest, positive impact of public debt on GDP in these EU member states, in which the share of public debt in GDP was close to 65%. Therefore, such a share of public debt in GDP was an optimum from the impact of public debt on economic growth point of view.
0,4 0,3 0,2 Elasticity of GDP to public debt 0,1 0,0 -0,1 -0,2 -0,3 -0,4 -0,5 -0,6 0 20 40 60 80 100 120 Public debt in relation to GDP [in %]

Figure 4. Elasticity of GDP to public debt and the ratio of public debt to GDP in the EU member countries in the period 20002010 Source: Own calculations.

Taking into account the values of elasticity coefficients of public debt to GDP and public debt to GDP in the EU member countries it was not identified a significant relationship between these variables. However, it should be noticed that the negative values of elasticity coefficients of public to GDP were confirmed in these countries where the share of public debt in GDP was between 20% and 60%.
0,15 0,10 0,05 Elasticity of public debt to GDP 0,00 -0,05 -0,10 -0,15 -0,20 -0,25 -0,30 -0,35 0 20 40 60 80 100 120 Public debt in relation to GDP [in %]

Figure 5. Elasticity of public debt to GDP and the ratio of public debt to GDP in the EU member countries in the period 20002010 Source: Own calculations.

300

Volume V/ Issue 3(13)/ Fall 2010

To sum up, an optimal share of public debt to GDP, expressing the highest, positive impact on economic growth in the EU member countries was close to 65%. While the negative impact of economic growth on the size of public debt was found in these EU member countries, whose public debt was from 20% to 40% of GDP. Taking into account public debt forecasts to 2020 in selected developed countries and emerging markets made by Deutsche Bank, it should be noted that among examined EU member countries, we should expect a positive impact of public debt on economic growth in Poland, Czech Republic, Hungary and Romania, in which public debt will be closest to the optimum level in 2020.
Table 4. Matrix of public debt projections by 2020 in selected EU member countries Developed countries Medium (73.7<debt Low (debt ratio<73.7) ratio<131.4) Denmark, Sweden Belgium Germany, Ireland, Spain France, Slovakia, UK Emerging markets Medium (20<debt Low (debt ratio<20) ratio<52.2)

The share of public debt in GDP/Tendency Falling Stable Increasing The share of public debt in GDP/Tendency Falling Stable Increasing

High (debt ratio>131.4) Italy Greece, Portugal High (debt ratio>52.2) Poland Czech Rep., Hungary, Romania

Source: Deutsche Bank Research (2010).

However, according to data reported in the above table, the most of developed EU member countries will perceive a negative impact of public debt on economic growth in 2020, because the level of public debt in these countries will significantly exceed its optimal size, 5. Conclusions On the basis of the results of investigation concerning the relationship between public debt and economic growth in the EU during the first quarter of 2000 to the first quarter of 2010 we can point at several key conclusions. Firstly, it was found that one of the factors that determined GDP growth in the EU in the period 20002010 were changes in public debt. Namely, average elasticity coefficient of public debt to economic growth amounted to 0.3. On the other hand, one of the factors which determined the size of public debt in the EU in the period 20002010 was changes in GDP. In this case, average elasticity coefficient of GDP to public debt in the EU amounted to 0.4. Moreover, it was estimated that changes in GDP accounted for public debt variability in much more degree than the scale in which public debt changes accounted for GDP variability in the EU. Secondly, it was found that elasticity coefficients of public debt to economic growth and economic growth to public debt significantly differed in the individual EU member countries. The highest absolute values of impact coefficients of public debt to GDP were reported in Spain and Ireland, but the lowest value in Latvia. However, the highest absolute values of impact coefficients of GDP to public debt were found in Finland and the smallest in Spain, Ireland, Slovenia, Sweden, Denmark, Netherlands and Cyprus. Thirdly, it was affirmed that the highest, positive impact of public debt on GDP took place in the EU member countries, where the share of public debt in GDP was close to 65%. What is more, there was not found a significant relationship between the values of elasticity coefficients of GDP to public debt and the share of public debt in the GDP in individual EU member countries, but it was noted the existence of negative values of elasticity coefficients of public debt to GDP in these countries where the share of public debt in GDP was from 20% to 60%.

301

Journal of Applied Economic Sciences

References [1] Biondo, A.E. 2010. A growth rate for sustainable economy. Journal of Applied Economic Sciences. 2(12): 821. [2] Diamond, P. 1965. National debt in a neoclassical growth model. American Economic Review. 55: 11261150. [3] Elbadaw, I.A., Ndulu, B.J., and Ndungu N. 1997. Debt overhang and economic growth in Sub Saharan Africa in: Iqbal Zubair. Kanbur Ravi (eds.). External finance for lowincome countries. Washington. International Monetary Fund. [4] Feldstein, M. 2004. Budget deficits and national debt. K. Jha Memorial Lecture at the Reserve Bank of India in Mumbai. India. 12: 114. [5] Ferreira, C. 2009. Public debt and economic growth: a granger causality panel data approach. Technical University of Lisbon Working Papers. 24: 117. [6] Greiner, A., Fincke, B. 2009. Public debt and economic growth. SpringerVerlag. Berlin. [7] Keho, Y. 2010. Budget deficits and economic growth: causality evidence and policy implications for WAEMU countries. European Journal of Economics. Finance and Administrative Sciences. 18: 99104. [8] Kumar, M.S., and Woo, J. 2010. Public debt and growth. International Monetary Fund Working Paper. 174: 145. [9] Modigliani, F. 1961. Longrun implications of alternative fiscal policies and the burden of the national debt. Economic Journal. 71: 730755. [10] Moore, W., and Chrystol, T., 2008. A metaanalysis of the relationship between debt and growth. Munich Personal RePEc Archive Paper. 21474: 123. [11] Patillo, C., Poirson, H., and Ricci L. 2004. What are the channels through which external debt affects growth? International Monetary Fund Working Paper. 15: 133. [12] Public debt in 2020. 2010. Deutsche Bank Research. March 24. [13] Reinhart, C.M., and Rogoff, K.S. 2010. Growth in a time of debt. American Economic Review. 100(2): 573578. [14] SaintPaul, G. 1992. Fiscal policy in an endogenous growth model. Quarterly Journal of Economics. 107: 12431259. [15] Saleh, A.S. 2003. The budget deficit and economic performance: a survey. University of Wollongong. Faculty of Commerce Economics Working Papers. 78: 153. [16] Schclarek, A. 2005. Debt and economic growth in developing and industrial countries. Lund University Working Papers. 34: 139. [17] Smyth, D.J., and Hsing,Yu. 1995. In search of an optimal debt ratio for economic growth. Contemporary Economic Policy. 13(4): 5159.

302

You might also like